Testing for One-Factor Models versus Stochastic Volatility Models



(b) Let S →∞. Suppose that, as n, m, ξn-1 →∞, nξn →∞ and nξn2 0 , and, for any ε > 0
arbitrarily small, m/n1 -ε 0; then do not reject H0 if

Zn,m CVαS

and reject otherwise. This rule provides a test with asymptotic size equal to α and asymptotic
unit power.

As mentioned above, our test is designed to compare two classes of models, namely the one-
factor diffusion models and the stochastic volatility models, regardless of the specification of the
drift term. Therefore, if for example model (1) is augmented by adding another factor into the drift
term (see e.g. Hull and White, 1994), our test will still fail to reject the null hypothesis considered,
because the drift term is, over a fixed time span, of a smaller order of probability than the diffusion
term and so is asymptotically negligible.

2.3 Market Microstructures and jumps

The asymptotic theory derived in the previous subsection relies on the fact that the underlying
process is a continuous semi-martingale. However, some recent financial literature has pointed
out the effects of possible jumps and market microstructure error on realized volatility (see e.g.
Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard, 2004c,d, Corradi and Distaso, 2004, Andersen, Bollerslev and
Diebold, 2003 for jumps, and Alt-Sahalia, Mykland and Zhang, 2003, Zhang, Mykland and Alt-
Sahalia, 2003, Bandi and Russell, 2003, Hansen and Lunde, 2004 for microstructure noise).

We begin by analyzing the contribution of large and rare jumps. Suppose that the generating
process in (1) is augmented by a jump component,

d Xt = μ ( Xt )d t + d zt + σt d W1 ,t,

where σt = σ(Xt), and zt is a pure jump process.

The test statistics based on Zn,m,r are not robust to the presence of jumps. The intuitive reason
is that jumps have a different impact on the two components of the statistics, namely

L (n-1) rJ

n-1        Sn2 (Xi/n) and RVm,r .

i=1

In fact, in the presence of jumps, RVm,r converges to the integrated volatility process plus the sum
of the squared magnitudes of the jumps (see Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard, 2004c). Conversely,
n- 1 Σ!'ni1)rJ Sn(Xi/n) converges to integrated volatility plus the weighted sum of the squared
magnitudes of the jumps, where the weights depend on the local time of
Xt . Broadly speaking, a

11



More intriguing information

1. Fiscal Insurance and Debt Management in OECD Economies
2. Work Rich, Time Poor? Time-Use of Women and Men in Ireland
3. Public Debt Management in Brazil
4. The name is absent
5. Searching Threshold Inflation for India
6. Qualifying Recital: Lisa Carol Hardaway, flute
7. Do the Largest Firms Grow the Fastest? The Case of U.S. Dairies
8. The Folklore of Sorting Algorithms
9. The name is absent
10. The Impact of Financial Openness on Economic Integration: Evidence from the Europe and the Cis
11. Meat Slaughter and Processing Plants’ Traceability Levels Evidence From Iowa
12. The Role of Immigration in Sustaining the Social Security System: A Political Economy Approach
13. Skills, Partnerships and Tenancy in Sri Lankan Rice Farms
14. For Whom is MAI? A theoretical Perspective on Multilateral Agreements on Investments
15. An Incentive System for Salmonella Control in the Pork Supply Chain
16. INTERPERSONAL RELATIONS AND GROUP PROCESSES
17. Investment and Interest Rate Policy in the Open Economy
18. Cultural Diversity and Human Rights: a propos of a minority educational reform
19. The Effects of Attendance on Academic Performance: Panel Data Evidence for Introductory Microeconomics
20. An Efficient Circulant MIMO Equalizer for CDMA Downlink: Algorithm and VLSI Architecture