Permanent and Transitory Policy Shocks in an Empirical Macro Model with Asymmetric Information



1 Introduction

Many models that are used to evaluate monetary policy assume, either explicitly or
implicitly, that (1) the inflation target of monetary policy is constant over the period
being analyzed; and, (2) the inflation target is known by all economic agents. Because
the actual and perceived inflation targets are equal and fixed, long-horizon expectations
are independent of short-run policy in such models.
1 Consequently, all monetary policy
actions are transient, and monetary policy appears to contribute only modestly to postwar
fluctuations in bond rates and economic activity.

The assumption that the inflation target is fully credible is surprisingly prevalent in
recent studies that examine historical policy or evaluate alternative policies. The literature
that evaluates policy alternatives under a constant and credible inflation target is vast.
Optimizing models used to evaluate alternative monetary policies, such as those reviewed in
Taylor (1999), generally assume a constant inflation target is common knowledge. Likewise,
standard atheoretical empirical analyses of policy effects implicitly assume a fixed policy
target or stationary nominal anchor. As noted by Kozicki and Tinsley (2001a), VARs
containing the levels of inflation and nominal interest rates imply constant and known
natural rates for those variables.

The traditional assumption that policy ob jectives were known to the private sector
was accompanied in early studies by an emphasis on the real effects of unanticipated
changes in monetary policy, such as Lucas (1973) and Sargent and Wallace (1976). Because
imperfectly observed policy is equivalent to unanticipated policy, several early studies
noted that monetary policy could have larger real effects in learning or filtering transitions
between persistent shifts in policy, such as Taylor (1980), Meyer and Webster (1982), and
1 The conclusion that long-run expectations are independent of short-run policy presumes that the policy
being followed is consistent with the goals of policy. For example, a Taylor-type (1993) interest rate rule
with an explicit numerical inflation target that doesnt satisfy the Taylor principle would generally lead to
explosive inflation and explosive private-sector inflation forecasts. Such a policy rule would be inconsistent
with the inflation target.



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. The name is absent
3. Optimal Rent Extraction in Pre-Industrial England and France – Default Risk and Monitoring Costs
4. A Computational Model of Children's Semantic Memory
5. Towards Teaching a Robot to Count Objects
6. The name is absent
7. Dementia Care Mapping and Patient-Centred Care in Australian residential homes: An economic evaluation of the CARE Study, CHERE Working Paper 2008/4
8. Errors in recorded security prices and the turn-of-the year effect
9. Personal Experience: A Most Vicious and Limited Circle!? On the Role of Entrepreneurial Experience for Firm Survival
10. The name is absent
11. Innovation Trajectories in Honduras’ Coffee Value Chain. Public and Private Influence on the Use of New Knowledge and Technology among Coffee Growers
12. Backpropagation Artificial Neural Network To Detect Hyperthermic Seizures In Rats
13. Fiscal federalism and Fiscal Autonomy: Lessons for the UK from other Industrialised Countries
14. The name is absent
15. ENERGY-RELATED INPUT DEMAND BY CROP PRODUCERS
16. Short- and long-term experience in pulmonary vein segmental ostial ablation for paroxysmal atrial fibrillation*
17. DIVERSITY OF RURAL PLACES - TEXAS
18. American trade policy towards Sub Saharan Africa –- a meta analysis of AGOA
19. Learning and Endogenous Business Cycles in a Standard Growth Model
20. Determinants of U.S. Textile and Apparel Import Trade