giving operating profits of
"■ = (1 - ω)psys,
(10)
and the remaining share ω goes to the intermediate supplier. The latter must decide in the previous
stage how much input xm to produce anticipating this share, which incurs a cost of xm units of
labor. Therefore, it maximizes
ʌ m = ωpsys — Xm,
(11)
which implies an intermediate and final output equal to
1
Xm = ys = A (αω)
(12)
with associated final price
1
ps = —.
aω
(13)
Using these results in (10) and (11), and recalling that specialized intermediate and final entrants
face probabilities η (r) and η (r) /r of being matched, their expected profits are respectively:
Q
πS = η(r) (1 — ω) A (αω) 1 q
(14)
and
πem = (1 — a) η^ ^ ωA (aω) 1 q .
r
(15)
Substituting (8) and (13) into (3) and (5) allows us to write aggregate demand as
(16)
where υ is the number of vertically integrated firms and f is the number of matched pairs of spe-
cialized producers that are active at time t.
3.2 Innovât ion
In the entry stage, the output from the R&D labs determines the laws of motion of υ and f. For
vertically integrated firms, we have
v = E⅛ — δυ (17)
kv
11