Outsourcing, Complementary Innovations and Growth



giving operating profits of

"■ = (1 - ω)psys,


(10)


and the remaining share ω goes to the intermediate supplier. The latter must decide in the previous


stage how much input xm to produce anticipating this share, which incurs a cost of xm units of


labor. Therefore, it maximizes


ʌ m = ωpsys Xm,


(11)


which implies an intermediate and final output equal to


1

Xm = ys = A (αω)


(12)


with associated final price


1

ps = —.


(13)


Using these results in (10) and (11), and recalling that specialized intermediate and final entrants


face probabilities η (r) and η (r) /r of being matched, their expected profits are respectively:


Q
πS = η(r) (1 ω) A (αω) 1 q


(14)


and


πem = (1 a) η^ ^ ωA () 1 q .
r


(15)


Substituting (8) and (13) into (3) and (5) allows us to write aggregate demand as


(16)


where υ is the number of vertically integrated firms and f is the number of matched pairs of spe-


cialized producers that are active at time t.


3.2 Innovât ion


In the entry stage, the output from the R&D labs determines the laws of motion of υ and f. For
vertically integrated firms, we have

v = E⅛ δυ                              (17)

kv


11




More intriguing information

1. TECHNOLOGY AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT: THE CASE OF PATENTS AND FIRM LOCATION IN THE SPANISH MEDICAL INSTRUMENTS INDUSTRY.
2. El Mercosur y la integración económica global
3. The name is absent
4. EU enlargement and environmental policy
5. Comparative study of hatching rates of African catfish (Clarias gariepinus Burchell 1822) eggs on different substrates
6. The name is absent
7. The name is absent
8. Distribution of aggregate income in Portugal from 1995 to 2000 within a SAM (Social Accounting Matrix) framework. Modeling the household sector
9. Beyond Networks? A brief response to ‘Which networks matter in education governance?’
10. The name is absent