The name is absent



and in what way geography matters, rather than pre-assuming its matters in all cases. Also note that, in
evolutionary analysis, one does not determine
a priori at which spatial level the analysis should be carried
out. Instead, the relevant spatial level is an outcome of the empirical analysis itself. This can be realised
when applying a multi-level approach (e.g., using spatial autocorrelation techniques), in which data at
various spatial scales have to determine at which spatial levels particular local phenomena can be best
explained (Van Oort 2002). This would complement previous multi-level approaches assessing the impact
of different degrees of openness (in terms of a ratio local/non-local linkages) on regional development
(Asheim and Isaksen, 2002; Bathelt et al. 2003).

Institutional and evolutionary economics have some methodological differences, yet substantially they
share important assumptions and ideas. These have already been discussed above in the context of
economic theory more generally. In the context of economic geography, the most important idea is to
view place as a context constraining behaviour
viz. the notion of ‘real places’. In evolutionary economics,
this notion is known in a more specific context, that of innovation systems. Each territory has a unique set
of characteristics, including identity, resources, institutions, industry-mix and relations within and outside
the region. Consequently, the universalistic account of economic geography advocated by neoclassicals is
rejected. Even is one would accept the view that the new economic geography allows for historical
specificity and path dependence, this is an outcome of spatial process and not of differences in territories.
As Martin puts it (1999), history is not regarded as ‘real history’: “there is no sense of the real and
context-specific periods of time over which spatial agglomerations have evolved” (p. 76). An
institutionalist view stresses that spatial outcomes are not solely the outcome of spatial processes of
increasing returns (in the space of flows) but also as a function of important regional differences (in the
space of places). As Martin (1999) has put it, “path dependence does not just ‘produce’ geography as in
the ‘new economic geography’ models; places produce path dependence” (p. 80).

The way real places are conceptualised in institutional and evolutionary economics, however, is rather
different. Evolutionary models typically share the assumption of neutral space with neoclassical
economics, and can be criticised for this from an institutional perspective. For example, the Polya
‘proportion-to-probability’ models and firm demography models simulating spatial patterns of new
industries assume no initial regional differences. In these models, neutral spaces are assumed to exist
initially, as in new economic geography models, and a combination of historical accidents and increasing
returns create a spatial pattern. However, in more applied evolutionary approaches, evolutionary
economics emphasis that the central concepts of bounded rationality and localised search can, in principle,
be extended towards the geographical realm of analysis (Boschma and Lambooy 1999; Essleztbichler
2002; Klepper 2002a; cf. Pred 1966). Agents innovative in directions constrained by routines that have
been build over
time and within a particular geographically localised context. What is more, this context
co-evolves with economic development as technological change put institutional and social structure
under pressure. Thus, despite being a contextual approach, an evolutionary approach is always cautious
not to overestimate the role of the environment as a determinant of economic dynamics. Organisations and
their surrounding environment co-evolve over time: territory-specific assets are constantly transformed,
upgraded, or they get locked-in by the actions and repeated interactions of local agents. That is,
organisations continually adapt and transform, intentionally or not, their environment (Metcalfe, 1994).

In particular, the evolutionary approach argues that the selection pressure of existing spatial structures
is rather weak when new industries emerge (Boschma and Van der Knaap, 1997). Under certain
circumstances, there are good reasons to assume that place-specific features do not determine the location

20



More intriguing information

1. EU enlargement and environmental policy
2. Consumer Networks and Firm Reputation: A First Experimental Investigation
3. On the Existence of the Moments of the Asymptotic Trace Statistic
4. The name is absent
5. Confusion and Reinforcement Learning in Experimental Public Goods Games
6. Financial Markets and International Risk Sharing
7. RETAIL SALES: DO THEY MEAN REDUCED EXPENDITURES? GERMAN GROCERY EVIDENCE
8. Three Strikes and You.re Out: Reply to Cooper and Willis
9. Intertemporal Risk Management Decisions of Farmers under Preference, Market, and Policy Dynamics
10. Tissue Tracking Imaging for Identifying the Origin of Idiopathic Ventricular Arrhythmias: A New Role of Cardiac Ultrasound in Electrophysiology
11. Social Balance Theory
12. National urban policy responses in the European Union: Towards a European urban policy?
13. The name is absent
14. Stakeholder Activism, Managerial Entrenchment, and the Congruence of Interests between Shareholders and Stakeholders
15. ADJUSTMENT TO GLOBALISATION: A STUDY OF THE FOOTWEAR INDUSTRY IN EUROPE
16. Foreign direct investment in the Indian telecommunications sector
17. Database Search Strategies for Proteomic Data Sets Generated by Electron Capture Dissociation Mass Spectrometry
18. An institutional analysis of sasi laut in Maluku, Indonesia
19. The name is absent
20. The Role of Evidence in Establishing Trust in Repositories