THEORY OE INTERNATIONAL VALUES
635
г x — N; where r is an improper fraction, in cases instanced by
the author, ⅛ and ⅝.1 Employing this conception, Mangoldt
enunciates that condition of equilibrium which would now be
described as the intersection of two curves. ■
He then goes on to consider the phenomenon which would
now be described as the multiple intersection of demand and
supply curves (pp. 228, 229, and cf. § 68). His views on this
curious subject are very interesting. He thinks that in general
of several possible positions of equilibrium that one tends to
be realised which is most favourable to the more active of the
two nations. But there are stated some probabilities on the other
side, which seem not very easy to apprehend (p. 229). It may
be observed that Mangoldt, like Mill,2 supposes neutral equilibrium
—the coincidence of the two curves as we may say—to be
possible.
So far the cost of production has been assumed to be con-
stant, whatever the amount produced. Mangoldt next supposes
(p. 232) the relation between cost and quantity which is now
called the law of diminishing returns to prevail, and illustrates
the general theory by a particular example, which is rendered
more workable by resorting to the simple law of demand at first
assumed—namely, that the quantity demanded is in inverse ratio
to the cost.
Finally, the cost of transport is taken into consideration
(p. 233). Mangoldt propounds the remarkable theory that upon
a certain hypothesis the carrying trade between two countries
tends to fall to that one which has the smaller absolute produc-
tivity (p. 235). The distinction between the ‘ active ’ and ‘ passive ’
nation which we have already met with in connection with
plural equilibrium here recurs (p. 240). Mangoldt illustrates his
theories more suo by laborious examples. He sums up the section
on cost of transport in a series of propositions, among which the
following—very freely paraphrased—seem the most remarkable.
(1) The carrying trade between two nations tends to fall into
1 As I understand, i£ (as in Cournot’s demand curve) x be the price and y the
r
corresponding quantity demanded, = f (x) ; we have f (m x) = — f (x).
In the particular case where the law applies only to small changes of x, put
dy '
m = (1 + α), α small. Whence y + a ~l = y — ary.
Above, p. 610.
More intriguing information
1. Linking Indigenous Social Capital to a Global Economy2. The name is absent
3. Federal Tax-Transfer Policy and Intergovernmental Pre-Commitment
4. HACCP AND MEAT AND POULTRY INSPECTION
5. The Impact of Cognitive versus Affective Aspects on Consumer Usage of Financial Service Delivery Channels
6. The name is absent
7. Protocol for Past BP: a randomised controlled trial of different blood pressure targets for people with a history of stroke of transient ischaemic attack (TIA) in primary care
8. Social Irresponsibility in Management
9. IMPLICATIONS OF CHANGING AID PROGRAMS TO U.S. AGRICULTURE
10. Disturbing the fiscal theory of the price level: Can it fit the eu-15?