Competition In or For the Field: Which is Better



engaging in production). In these cases functions S and π can be derived from standard demand and cost
functions.

In all the cases that follow we assume that the value of the marginal unit atq is P(q), with P0 < 0. We also
assume that the inverse function of
P, P-1(p) D(p) is well defined in the appropriate range. Obviously
D0 < 0. Agent i incurs in total cost c(qi) when producing qi units of output at a given plant, with c0 > 0 and
c00 0.12

We find that in all three cases a sufficient condition for a joint contract to be better for the principal is
that marginal revenue be decreasing in quantities. In addition, we show that whenever this holds, a social
planner also prefers a joint auction. The following two lemmas, which are proven in the appendix, will be
useful when establishing this result:

Lemma 1 (i) P0(q) = DPq)); (ii) P00(q) = -{DPq}3 ; (iii) D0(p) = P(D^; (iv) D0(p) =   PPDp}3.

Lemma 2 2P0(q) +qP00(q) < 0 if and only if DD00 - 2(D0)2 < 0.

3.1 Procurement

We first consider fixed-price procurement.13 The principal wants to buy an input as cheaply as possible,
and can choose between one or two suppliers. Clearly, the principal cares (directly) only about the price
p
paid per unit, and not about production costs c (of course, as in any principal-agent problem, the principal
cares about the agents’ costs indirectly through the participation constraint). Hence
S (p) pD(s)ds is the
principal’s surplus, and
π(p) = 2pD(p) - c D2p)^) is the surplus of each agent with a separate auction; with
a joint auction the agent’s surplus is 2
π(p). In this case pm = argmax 12pD(p) - c D2p)^) } and p is such
that
2pD(p) - c (D2p)´ = 0. Therefore

S0  =  -D < 0,

S00  =  -D0 >0

(i.e. S is convex and Corollary 1 does not apply). Also,

0 = 2 [D + (p - c' ) D ],

12This condition implies no loss of generality. If c00 < 0, marginal and average costs are decreasing and auctioning jointly is
clearly better.

13In fixed-price procurement contracts, the buyer and the seller agree on a price, and the seller assumes all cost risk. At the
other extreme, in a cost-plus contract the buyer reimburses the seller’s cost. As argued in Laffont and Tirole (1993, p. 662), only
fixed-price contracts are relevant when it is too costly for the buyer to audit the subcost of the supplier.



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. The Prohibition of the Proposed Springer-ProSiebenSat.1-Merger: How much Economics in German Merger Control?
3. PACKAGING: A KEY ELEMENT IN ADDED VALUE
4. The name is absent
5. Prizes and Patents: Using Market Signals to Provide Incentives for Innovations
6. The name is absent
7. Are class size differences related to pupils’ educational progress and classroom processes? Findings from the Institute of Education Class Size Study of children aged 5-7 Years
8. How does an infant acquire the ability of joint attention?: A Constructive Approach
9. Initial Public Offerings and Venture Capital in Germany
10. Banking Supervision in Integrated Financial Markets: Implications for the EU