Competition In or For the Field: Which is Better



engaging in production). In these cases functions S and π can be derived from standard demand and cost
functions.

In all the cases that follow we assume that the value of the marginal unit atq is P(q), with P0 < 0. We also
assume that the inverse function of
P, P-1(p) D(p) is well defined in the appropriate range. Obviously
D0 < 0. Agent i incurs in total cost c(qi) when producing qi units of output at a given plant, with c0 > 0 and
c00 0.12

We find that in all three cases a sufficient condition for a joint contract to be better for the principal is
that marginal revenue be decreasing in quantities. In addition, we show that whenever this holds, a social
planner also prefers a joint auction. The following two lemmas, which are proven in the appendix, will be
useful when establishing this result:

Lemma 1 (i) P0(q) = DPq)); (ii) P00(q) = -{DPq}3 ; (iii) D0(p) = P(D^; (iv) D0(p) =   PPDp}3.

Lemma 2 2P0(q) +qP00(q) < 0 if and only if DD00 - 2(D0)2 < 0.

3.1 Procurement

We first consider fixed-price procurement.13 The principal wants to buy an input as cheaply as possible,
and can choose between one or two suppliers. Clearly, the principal cares (directly) only about the price
p
paid per unit, and not about production costs c (of course, as in any principal-agent problem, the principal
cares about the agents’ costs indirectly through the participation constraint). Hence
S (p) pD(s)ds is the
principal’s surplus, and
π(p) = 2pD(p) - c D2p)^) is the surplus of each agent with a separate auction; with
a joint auction the agent’s surplus is 2
π(p). In this case pm = argmax 12pD(p) - c D2p)^) } and p is such
that
2pD(p) - c (D2p)´ = 0. Therefore

S0  =  -D < 0,

S00  =  -D0 >0

(i.e. S is convex and Corollary 1 does not apply). Also,

0 = 2 [D + (p - c' ) D ],

12This condition implies no loss of generality. If c00 < 0, marginal and average costs are decreasing and auctioning jointly is
clearly better.

13In fixed-price procurement contracts, the buyer and the seller agree on a price, and the seller assumes all cost risk. At the
other extreme, in a cost-plus contract the buyer reimburses the seller’s cost. As argued in Laffont and Tirole (1993, p. 662), only
fixed-price contracts are relevant when it is too costly for the buyer to audit the subcost of the supplier.



More intriguing information

1. Neural Network Modelling of Constrained Spatial Interaction Flows
2. Estimating the Impact of Medication on Diabetics' Diet and Lifestyle Choices
3. Do the Largest Firms Grow the Fastest? The Case of U.S. Dairies
4. The name is absent
5. Survey of Literature on Covered and Uncovered Interest Parities
6. Correlation Analysis of Financial Contagion: What One Should Know Before Running a Test
7. Strategic Policy Options to Improve Irrigation Water Allocation Efficiency: Analysis on Egypt and Morocco
8. APPLICATIONS OF DUALITY THEORY TO AGRICULTURE
9. A Critical Examination of the Beliefs about Learning a Foreign Language at Primary School
10. A Brief Introduction to the Guidance Theory of Representation
11. Three Strikes and You.re Out: Reply to Cooper and Willis
12. Giant intra-abdominal hydatid cysts with multivisceral locations
13. L'organisation en réseau comme forme « indéterminée »
14. The Impact of Hosting a Major Sport Event on the South African Economy
15. New issues in Indian macro policy.
16. Heterogeneity of Investors and Asset Pricing in a Risk-Value World
17. Input-Output Analysis, Linear Programming and Modified Multipliers
18. Ultrametric Distance in Syntax
19. The name is absent
20. The Demand for Specialty-Crop Insurance: Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard