Globalization, Divergence and Stagnation



to cease. Note that this result, like Proposition 1, requires σ0 (i.e., an elasticity
of substitution between goods larger than one): with
σ = 0 the cut-off commodity
z and the wage ratio ω would not depend on technology, because every country
and sector would bene
fit equally from any improvement in a(i), and (23) would not
depend on
θ. Also, sector-specific technical process is a key assumption for deriving
Proposition 2. In a setup with factor-speci
fic innovations, as in Acemoglu and Zili-
botti (200
1), the market size for any innovation depends on exogenous endowments
that are una
ffected by specialization and trade: for this reason, incentives to invest
in R&D would never go to zero even if
θ = 0.21

Comparing the growth rate in free trade, (23), and autarky, (14), and noting
that (23) is a continuous function of
θ with limθ→θ*>θ gFT = 0, proves the following:

Proposition 2 For any σ (0,1), there exists a level θ such that, if θθ, the
world growth rate is lower in free trade than in autarky.

What happens during the transitional dynamics from autarky to the free trade
equilibrium? Since technology adjusts slowly, initially the equilibrium is determined
by equations (
19) and (20) using the pre-trade values of α(z). In general, the wage in
both countries will jump up, as specialization increases the overall e
fficiency of the
whole economy. Then, if the instantaneous wage ratio falls short of its long run free-
trade value, there will be a period in which innovation is biased towards Northern
sectors. During the transition, the Northern relative wage will rise and at the same
time
firms will move to the South where production costs are lower. Note that in a
trading environment with asymmetric IPRs protection, divergence and stagnation
are closely related: it is the growing cost of production in the wealthier North that
induces the relocation of production towards the South (an important phenomenon
in recent years) which in turn makes more sectors subject to weak IPRs and lowers
the global incentives for innovation.

2.3 Why Are IPRs Not Protected in the South?

The previous analysis suggests that Southern countries may benefit from the en-
forcement of IPRs: it would attract more appropriate innovations and foster world
growth. It is then interesting to ask why these policies are often not adopted. A
first

21As a consequence, in Acemolgu and Zilibotti (2001) trade opening has no effect on the world
growth rate.

17



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. The name is absent
3. FOREIGN AGRICULTURAL SERVICE PROGRAMS AND FOREIGN RELATIONS
4. O funcionalismo de Sellars: uma pesquisa histδrica
5. The name is absent
6. Segmentación en la era de la globalización: ¿Cómo encontrar un segmento nuevo de mercado?
7. Imitation in location choice
8. The name is absent
9. The name is absent
10. Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in Models with Endogenous Fertility