Food Prices and Overweight Patterns in Italy



estimate elasticities of demand, we assumed a multistage decision process (Edgerton,
1997). The estimated system is conditional on the choice of purchasing goods that
consists of non-durables in a previous non-modelled stage and is determined as part
of consumers’ overall decision regarding how to allocate expenditure across the full
range of goods. In fact as the expenditure is allocated within non-durables, only
in the second (conditional) stage consumers decide how to allocate across healthy
foods, unhealthy foods, and other foods and non-durables
8 . In this case, income
elasticity and Hicksian price elasticities are computed as follows:

= ∂qi y = ∂wi 1 + i
ηi   ∂y qi    log ywi

(8)


with i = 1, 2, 3. The expression for expenditure elasticity indicates that a good
is a luxury if
ηi > 1 and a necessity if ηi < 1. The compensated price elasticities
are given as:

ηij =


∂hi Pj

∂pj hi


∂wi 1

log Pj Wi


+ wj - δij


(9)


where the partial derivatives in (8) and (9) are obtained from equation (7) and
i,j=1,2,3. Then, the uncompensated price elasticities are obtained from the Slutsky
equation,
εij = ηij - wjηi .

One formal way of testing the substitution effects between healthy and unhealthy
foods is to calculate their cross-price elasticities. According to Hicks (1936),
ηij >
0 indicates substitutability among goods, ηij < 0 complementarity, and ηij = 0
independence.

One important property of the Slutsky equation is that the estimated parameters
of the matrix are symmetric. But unlike Allen’s (1938) elasticity of substitution,
the Hicksian framework does not impose symmetry restrictions in elasticity terms.
In line with the aims of this paper, we can verify how changes in the prices of
unhealthy versus healthy foods simultaneously affect the relative cost of purchasing
quantities of these categories of foods. The framework is therefore close to that of
Auld and Powell (2009). If, as shown in section 2, changes in healthy food prices are
higher than in unhealthy food prices during the last decade in Italy, we can predict
greater total calorie intake, generated by a substitution towards unhealthy foods,
which determines an increase in the consumption of energy-dense foods. In addition,

8 In a complete demand system, we should consider previously at least the choice of how to allocate total expen-
diture between goods and services for consumption (Gorman, 1995).

16



More intriguing information

1. Ultrametric Distance in Syntax
2. Epistemology and conceptual resources for the development of learning technologies
3. The name is absent
4. The name is absent
5. Infrastructure Investment in Network Industries: The Role of Incentive Regulation and Regulatory Independence
6. The name is absent
7. The name is absent
8. Transport system as an element of sustainable economic growth in the tourist region
9. EFFICIENCY LOSS AND TRADABLE PERMITS
10. Social Balance Theory
11. Secondary school teachers’ attitudes towards and beliefs about ability grouping
12. The name is absent
13. The name is absent
14. The name is absent
15. Exchange Rate Uncertainty and Trade Growth - A Comparison of Linear and Nonlinear (Forecasting) Models
16. Place of Work and Place of Residence: Informal Hiring Networks and Labor Market Outcomes
17. Emissions Trading, Electricity Industry Restructuring and Investment in Pollution Abatement
18. Inflation Targeting and Nonlinear Policy Rules: The Case of Asymmetric Preferences (new title: The Fed's monetary policy rule and U.S. inflation: The case of asymmetric preferences)
19. Education and Development: The Issues and the Evidence
20. Why unwinding preferences is not the same as liberalisation: the case of sugar