The name is absent



two parties in government always have the same vote share in equilibrium : equa-
tion (3.1) implies that
NvC1 = NvC2 . Moreover, since all electoral districts are
homogenous, either the two parties in government win the whole legislature, or
the opposition wins the whole legislature, depending on the realization of δ.Ifthe
two parties in government win, a coin is tossed to award the seat to one of them
district by district. With a continuum of districts, in equilibrium each winning
party in government ends up with half the seats in the legislature.14

This argument implies that the equilibrium expected seat share of party P =
1, 2 in a coalition government, is:

E(Nsp) = 1 Prob[Nvp NvC] ,                   (4.1)

2

where Nvc denotes the minimum threshold needed to win the election in any one
of the identical districts given the number of parties. As before, the expectation
and the probability refers to the uncertainty regarding the realization of δ. If the
opposition is also split in two parties (i.e., N = IV), we have
IVvc = 1. To win,
the coalition parties in government thus need to carry at least half the votes in any
district; since the votes are split equally between them (as they are between the
opposition parties), any one of the parties in government needs to win a quarter
of the votes in any district. If instead the opposition consists of a single party
(i.e., N = III),
IIIvc = 3. As the vote for the government is split in half between
the coalition parties, the government parties win the elections only if each of them
has a vote share at least as large as that of the single opposition party.

Recall that the random variable δ has a uniform distribution with mean 0 and
density ψ. Using (3.1) and simplifying, we then obtain the expected seat share
in the next legislature, at the policy formation stage, for a party in a coalition
government:

E(NsC) = 4 + (4 -N vc)φ +                           (4.2)

ψ              14

+4[(VP - V*c) + 2∑(vJ - VJ)].

J=3

This expression is similar to that under proportional elections, equation (3.2).
The differences are that: (i) the density φ of the idiosyncratic reservation utility

14 The reader may wonder why, then, the coalition parties do not strategically agree to split
the districts among themselves running only a single coalition candidate in each district. But in
our simple model, these agreements would not be self-enforcing. To satisfactorily address this
issue, a richer model is needed.

21



More intriguing information

1. GROWTH, UNEMPLOYMENT AND THE WAGE SETTING PROCESS.
2. SOME ISSUES IN LAND TENURE, OWNERSHIP AND CONTROL IN DISPERSED VS. CONCENTRATED AGRICULTURE
3. Changing spatial planning systems and the role of the regional government level; Comparing the Netherlands, Flanders and England
4. Estimating the Economic Value of Specific Characteristics Associated with Angus Bulls Sold at Auction
5. The name is absent
6. The resources and strategies that 10-11 year old boys use to construct masculinities in the school setting
7. The name is absent
8. Innovation Trajectories in Honduras’ Coffee Value Chain. Public and Private Influence on the Use of New Knowledge and Technology among Coffee Growers
9. Uncertain Productivity Growth and the Choice between FDI and Export
10. Dementia Care Mapping and Patient-Centred Care in Australian residential homes: An economic evaluation of the CARE Study, CHERE Working Paper 2008/4