The name is absent



If this condition is met, the four-party system is an equilibrium under majoritarian
elections. But this condition is always the case, since as noted in Footnote 16 the
right-hand side of (4.12) is smaller than 1, while the left-hand side is above 1.
Hence, under majoritarian elections too, a four party equilibrium always exists.

But now, it is not the only equilibrium. A two-party system is also an equilib-
rium if all groups prefer to merge rather than to remain split, given that the two
opposition groups have also merged, namely if :

- IIW12 IIIW1 .                         (4.13)

2

The right-hand side of (4.13) is the expected payoff to group 1 of remaining a
group-specific party while the opposing groups have merged. The left-hand side
of (4.13) is the expected payoff accruing to group 1 if it merges with group 2:
the term
IIW12 is divided in half because each group gets half the party payoff
resulting from the merger.

Given the results stated above, condition (4.13) for a two-party equilibrium
can be re-written as:

1+2 2Ψ .                        (4.14)

γ ^ 3φ                              (    )

Note that the left-hand sides of (4.14) and (4.12) are the same, but the right-hand
side of (4.14) is twice as large as the right-hand side of (4.12). Hence, for some
parameter values both a two-party and a four-party equilibrium exist (since the
left hand side of (4.14) cannot exceed 2, this requires that
γ1).

A two-party equilibrium is more likely to exist if ψ∕φ = Std(ω)∕Std(δ) is
large. That is, if aggregate voter mobility is large relative to within-group voter
mobility. As the reader may recall, the same conditions make it more likely that
equilibrium rents are higher under proportional elections. This makes intuitive
sense. If, say, aggregate voter mobility is large (Std(
δ) small), the election outcome
is very uncertain. Then, the electoral advantage of a large party facing two small
parties is very significant, cf. (4.4) and (4.3), which naturally raises the incentive
to merge. At the same time, rent extraction is punished much more strongly by
the voters under majoritarian elections: recall that voter utilities are multiplied
by
ψ rather than φ in the expression for expected seat shares. Similarly, small
within-group voter mobility (Std(
ω) large) raises the electoral advantage ofa large
party.

We summarize the results of this section as follows:

Proposition 4

28



More intriguing information

1. THE WAEA -- WHICH NICHE IN THE PROFESSION?
2. Strengthening civil society from the outside? Donor driven consultation and participation processes in Poverty Reduction Strategies (PRSP): the Bolivian case
3. Emissions Trading, Electricity Industry Restructuring and Investment in Pollution Abatement
4. MICROWORLDS BASED ON LINEAR EQUATION SYSTEMS: A NEW APPROACH TO COMPLEX PROBLEM SOLVING AND EXPERIMENTAL RESULTS
5. Social Cohesion as a Real-life Phenomenon: Exploring the Validity of the Universalist and Particularist Perspectives
6. The name is absent
7. Micro-strategies of Contextualization Cross-national Transfer of Socially Responsible Investment
8. FDI Implications of Recent European Court of Justice Decision on Corporation Tax Matters
9. TECHNOLOGY AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT: THE CASE OF PATENTS AND FIRM LOCATION IN THE SPANISH MEDICAL INSTRUMENTS INDUSTRY.
10. CONSIDERATIONS CONCERNING THE ROLE OF ACCOUNTING AS INFORMATIONAL SYSTEM AND ASSISTANCE OF DECISION
11. Errors in recorded security prices and the turn-of-the year effect
12. The Integration Order of Vector Autoregressive Processes
13. The name is absent
14. Innovation in commercialization of pelagic fish: the example of "Srdela Snack" Franchise
15. The Context of Sense and Sensibility
16. Internationalization of Universities as Internationalization of Bildung
17. Ruptures in the probability scale. Calculation of ruptures’ values
18. Altruism and fairness in a public pension system
19. The name is absent
20. The name is absent