For the analysis of the optimal decision on information acquisition, we have to dis-
tinguish whether or not T > c∕ 2. This distinction does not influence the equilibrium
of the war of attrition in case both individuals know their provision cost, but it is
crucial for the nature of the equilibrium if at least one individual does not know his
cost of provision.13
Lemma 5 Suppose that Assumption 1 holds.
(i) Vfj N is strictly positive for all T.
(ii) Vffi' is strictly negative if T is sufficiently small and strictly increasing in T
for T ∈ (cb∕2,c∕2).
(iii) Suppose in case (N, I) the pure strategy equilibrium is selected. Then Vffi' is
strictly positive for all T > c∕2.
(iv) Suppose in case (N, I) the mixed strategy equilibrium is selected. Then Vffi1 is
continuous and strictly increasing in T for T ∈ (cffi2, c∕2 — clnpH).
Provided that the rival does not learn his cost of provision (σ7∙ = N), learning
one’s own cost always increases one’s expected payoff as the value of information
is positive (Lemma 5 part (i)). If instead the rival decides to learn his cost and
T is small, this result is reversed. However, as long as T < c∕ 2, an increasing
time limit makes waiting more costly in case the rival has a high provision cost,
which increases one’s own value of information (part (ii)). If T > c∕2, the value of
information depends on which equilibrium is selected in case (N, I). For the pure
strategy equilibrium, i’s value of information given that j learns his cost of provision,
Vi1, exhibits a discontinuity at T = c∕2 and is strictly positive for all T > c∕2 (part
(iii)). For the mixed strategy equilibrium, however, Vf is continuous at T = c∕2.
This continuity in T makes the analysis for the selected equilibrium more appealing.
Yet the following proposition holds independently of which equilibrium is selected in
case only one individual decides to learn his provision cost.14
13We still assume that Assumption 1 holds. If T < ¾∕2, then decisions on information are
irrelevant, since both individuals never concede before T. If T > c∏∕2, the war of attrition always
has equilibria where one of the individuals concedes immediately, independent of the decisions on
information.
14Due to the possible multiplicity of equilibria of the war of attrition in case of T > c∕2, depart-
ing from the analysis of the reduced form game makes the equilibrium analysis more complex in
16
More intriguing information
1. The name is absent2. Industrial Employment Growth in Spanish Regions - the Role Played by Size, Innovation, and Spatial Aspects
3. Non Linear Contracting and Endogenous Buyer Power between Manufacturers and Retailers: Empirical Evidence on Food Retailing in France
4. The name is absent
5. 09-01 "Resources, Rules and International Political Economy: The Politics of Development in the WTO"
6. Income Growth and Mobility of Rural Households in Kenya: Role of Education and Historical Patterns in Poverty Reduction
7. The name is absent
8. Name Strategy: Its Existence and Implications
9. Higher education funding reforms in England: the distributional effects and the shifting balance of costs
10. What Drives the Productive Efficiency of a Firm?: The Importance of Industry, Location, R&D, and Size