1 Introduction
Dragon-slaying and ballroom dancing are two famous examples1 for the provision of
a public good that induces a positive value for a certain group of individuals. One of
the individuals, however, has to pay some cost in order to provide the public good.
Such situations are often best described by a war of attrition: one volunteer is needed
for a certain task, and everyone prefers someone else to volunteer first and bear the
cost of provision. Typically, there is a disutility or waiting cost attached to the time
until a volunteer is found. In this paper, we study the individuals’ incentives to
obtain information about their own cost of provision of the public good prior to a
volunteering game or war of attrition.
Wars of attrition are used to model a large number of applications from different
fields. Besides dragon-slaying, many unpleasant situations like intervening in a fight,
calling the police in case of a fire or crime, household chores, fights between animals,
or market exit exhibit properties of wars of attrition.2 Organizations typically rely
on the voluntary performance of a large number of tasks. These tasks may have to be
performed repeatedly, and the cost of performing the task may then be well-known.
But often the individuals don’t know exactly how costly volunteering will turn out to
be. They may, for instance, only have a guess about the time involved in chairing a
university department or organizing a conference, but can acquire information about
this expenditure of time.
In many companies or institutions, staff meetings take place on a regular basis
and are used to allocate tasks to individuals. Before volunteering to perform a task,
employees typically have the possibility to find out about their cost of performing this
task, and they can do so by asking questions and collecting information. The ques-
tion, however, is what impact information acquisition has on the volunteering game
and whether individuals benefit from information acquisition. If such information
acquisition can be observed by the other individuals - for instance when employees
ask questions - there is a strategic value attached to the information: it can be used
1Cf. Bliss and Nalebuff (1984).
2Many more examples are given, e.g., by Bilodeau and Slivinski (1996), LaCasse et al. (2002),
or Otsubo and Rapoport (2008).
More intriguing information
1. Foreign direct investment in the Indian telecommunications sector2. The Formation of Wenzhou Footwear Clusters: How Were the Entry Barriers Overcome?
3. Lending to Agribusinesses in Zambia
4. Self-Help Groups and Income Generation in the Informal Settlements of Nairobi
5. DURABLE CONSUMPTION AS A STATUS GOOD: A STUDY OF NEOCLASSICAL CASES
6. The name is absent
7. The name is absent
8. Evolving robust and specialized car racing skills
9. The name is absent
10. Imitation in location choice