Inflation Targeting and Nonlinear Policy Rules: The Case of Asymmetric Preferences (new title: The Fed's monetary policy rule and U.S. inflation: The case of asymmetric preferences)



that confronts directly the issue involves the linearization of the exponential terms in (5) by
means of a first-order Taylor series expansion. We solve the resulting expression for
it and
prior to GMM estimation we replace expectations with realized values. As customary in the
empirical studies, we introduce a lagged dependent variable to capture interest rate smoothing
for which a number of explanations are provided in the literature (see Woodford, 1999, Sack
and Wieland, 2000, and Castelnuovo, 2003).6 We estimate the following policy rule:

it = (1 - ρ) P* + C1 (πt - π*) + c2yt + C3 (t - π*)2 + C4 (yt)2] + pit-1 + νt

(6)


where the coefficients are given by the expressions

_ kφ _ λφ _ αkφ _ λφγ
μ ’         
μ ’          2μ ’          2μ

and the error tems is defined as

νt ≡-(1 - ρ)


c1 (πt - Et-1πt) + c2 (yt - Et-1yt) +
+
c3 hπt2 - Et-1 (πt)2i + c4 hyt2 - Et-1 (yt)2i

l+et
I μ


The term in curly brackets is a linear combination of the forecast errors while et is the
remainder of the Taylor series approximation. Thus,
νt is orthogonal to any variable in
the information set available at time
t - 1.

Equation (6) makes clear that the reaction function parameters can only be interpreted as
convolutions of the coefficients representing policy makers’ preferences and those describing
the structure of the economy. Nevertheless, the estimates of the policy rule can now identify
the asymmetric preferences and - up to an additional assumption discussed below -
α =2c3 /c1
and γ = 2c4/c2 . The feedback coefficients c3 and c4 embody the relevant information such that
the joint restriction
c3 = c4 =0with c1 6=0 and c2 6=0 implies α = γ =0. Hence, testing the
hypothesis
H00 : c3 = c4 =0in (6) is equivalent to testing the hypothesis H0 : α = γ =0in (5).
Under the null of a linear reaction function, which fully corresponds to the null of symmetric
preferences, the statistics has an asymptotic
χ2 distribution with as many degrees of freedom
as the number of restrictions, and it can be successfully evaluated through a standard Wald
test.

In the absence of further assumptions our method only identifies the structural parameter
on output gap asymmetry,
γ, but neither the one on inflation, α, nor the target π* , separately.

6 Interestingly enough, a policy rule with no interest rate smoothing (estimates not reported but available
upon request) delivers an even stronger evidence of nonlinearity. It follows that the specification adopted in
this paper minimizes, if any, the degree of asymmetries. This observation deserves independent attention.

10



More intriguing information

1. Word searches: on the use of verbal and non-verbal resources during classroom talk
2. Konjunkturprognostiker unter Panik: Kommentar
3. Measuring and Testing Advertising-Induced Rotation in the Demand Curve
4. The name is absent
5. Parent child interaction in Nigerian families: conversation analysis, context and culture
6. Testing Hypotheses in an I(2) Model with Applications to the Persistent Long Swings in the Dmk/$ Rate
7. Restructuring of industrial economies in countries in transition: Experience of Ukraine
8. Housing Market in Malaga: An Application of the Hedonic Methodology
9. Density Estimation and Combination under Model Ambiguity
10. The Global Dimension to Fiscal Sustainability