Inflation Targeting and Nonlinear Policy Rules: The Case of Asymmetric Preferences (new title: The Fed's monetary policy rule and U.S. inflation: The case of asymmetric preferences)



representation (6).

3.5 Discussion

It is useful at this point to compare our estimates with the results from some recent studies
that also focus on the policy regime shift of 1979. Clarida, Gali' and Gertler (2000) estimate a
forward-looking linear reaction function for the pre-Volcker period and report values of
0.68 for
the coefficient on inflation (s.e.
= 0.06) and 0.28 for the coefficient on CBO output (s.e.= 0.08).
Their estimates suggest that neglecting the squared output gap, which significantly enters
our empirical specification with a negative sign, introduces a downward bias in the linear
estimate.8 Turning to the nonlinear specifications, Dolado, Maria-Dolores and Ruge-Murcia
(2004) use a Clarida, Gali' and Gertler-type of rule augmented with a generated regressor for
the conditional variance of inflation and find no evidence for this form of nonlinearity. Kim,
Osborn and Sensier (2004) use a semi-parametric method of estimation and show that only
the asymmetry over the output gap has been sizable.

The post-Volcker estimates of the parameters on the inflation level and the output gap
level are not statistically different from the values reported in Clarida, Gali' and Gertler (2000),
and therefore they confirm a limited role for nonlinearity during the last two decades. These
results are consistent with those in Kim, Osborne and Sensier (2004) while they are only
marginally so with those in Dolado, Maria-Dolores and Ruge-Murcia (2004). The absence of
an output gap ob jective in the latter study however seems a natural candidate to explain the
difference. Lastly, we line up with earlier contributions in that the coefficient on the inflation
level becomes bigger than one moving from the pre- to the post-1979 period.

4Theaverageinflation bias

The estimates of the previous section support the notion of a novel inflation bias due to Cukier-
man (2002). In the presence of an asymmetric ob jective over the output gap and uncertainty
about the state of the economy, the monetary authorities face an incentive to respond more
aggressively to output contractions of a given amount than to output expansions of the same
magnitude. The reason is that the expected marginal benefit of a policy intervention is convex
in the output gap, implying that to satisfy the Euler equation and stimulate future aggregate

8 This result holds true also for the alternative measures of inflation and output gap.

14



More intriguing information

1. The changing face of Chicago: demographic trends in the 1990s
2. Labour Market Institutions and the Personal Distribution of Income in the OECD
3. The name is absent
4. Initial Public Offerings and Venture Capital in Germany
5. The InnoRegio-program: a new way to promote regional innovation networks - empirical results of the complementary research -
6. Partner Selection Criteria in Strategic Alliances When to Ally with Weak Partners
7. Technological progress, organizational change and the size of the Human Resources Department
8. Foreign Direct Investment and the Single Market
9. Innovation Policy and the Economy, Volume 11
10. A Regional Core, Adjacent, Periphery Model for National Economic Geography Analysis
11. The name is absent
12. Public-private sector pay differentials in a devolved Scotland
13. Improvements in medical care and technology and reductions in traffic-related fatalities in Great Britain
14. Draft of paper published in:
15. A Hybrid Neural Network and Virtual Reality System for Spatial Language Processing
16. La mobilité de la main-d'œuvre en Europe : le rôle des caractéristiques individuelles et de l'hétérogénéité entre pays
17. The name is absent
18. A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing (new title: Truly Costly Sequential Search and Oligopolistic Pricing,)
19. Should informal sector be subsidised?
20. The name is absent