The name is absent



Consider a life-time utility maximizing individual living in two periods. In period one, she
invests in her human capital. The investment is modeled as the time devoted to education, Z,
instead of leisure L, where Z + L is normalized to unity. Effort at school has opportunity costs
in terms of foregone leisure, but is an investment in future income. In period two, she
consumes her return to education. Assuming separability over time, the life-time utility in
expectational terms is

E{V} =u(1-Z) +rE{U(C)}

where r is the discount rate, C is consumption, and utility functions u and U are concave.

The welfare state is an institution that, in period two, transfers a fraction τ of the income from
high income earners to individuals with low income, and thus reduces the consumption
inequality in society. The uncertainty of the representative agent’s future income is captured
by the stochastic return of her education investment (ε), where E(ε) = 0 and Var
(ε)2 . We
write consumption in period two as

C = (1 ) y ( Z)(1 + ε) + τy

where the right hand side is the representative individual’s expected income after
redistribution. The deterministic part of the income is the productivity that depends on effort
in school, y(Z), with diminishing returns (y
'(Z) 0, y*(Z) 0). Because of income
redistribution only a fraction (1-τ) of the consumption is related to own productivity, y, while
the fraction τ is related to the average productivity in society, y. This formulation implies that
transfer-related income component can be written as
τ(y - y (Z)(1 + ε)), and that individuals
with the stochastic productivity y(1+ε) below (above) the societal mean productivity y will
have a positive (negative) transfer. Thus, the redistribution factor τ is an indicator of the
generosity of the welfare state. For simplicity, the implicit taxation and transfer rules are not
written down in the model.

The individual maximizes equation (1) with respect to effort Z subject to constraint (2). The
first order condition is

u'(1 - Z ) = (1 ) y'( Z) rE {u'( c)(1 + ε)}.                                                    (3)

In optimum, the marginal cost of effort is equal to the expected marginal return to effort. To
keep the analysis simple, we continue with the quadratic utility function
U2
( C ) = αC C2∕2. Then the first order condition (3) can be written as



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. Spatial agglomeration and business groups: new evidence from Italian industrial districts
3. The name is absent
4. The name is absent
5. A Regional Core, Adjacent, Periphery Model for National Economic Geography Analysis
6. Neural Network Modelling of Constrained Spatial Interaction Flows
7. The name is absent
8. The name is absent
9. A Bayesian approach to analyze regional elasticities
10. ‘Goodwill is not enough’
11. Non Linear Contracting and Endogenous Buyer Power between Manufacturers and Retailers: Empirical Evidence on Food Retailing in France
12. The Dynamic Cost of the Draft
13. The name is absent
14. Ability grouping in the secondary school: attitudes of teachers of practically based subjects
15. The name is absent
16. Rural-Urban Economic Disparities among China’s Elderly
17. Spatial patterns in intermunicipal Danish commuting
18. Examining Variations of Prominent Features in Genre Classification
19. The name is absent
20. Towards a Mirror System for the Development of Socially-Mediated Skills