Climate Policy under Sustainable Discounted Utilitarianism



The explicit algorithm defined by WT = U(cT) and repeated use of (5), with δt
determined by (3), is used for calculating SDU welfare in the empirical analysis. It
follows from (3) that the population-adjusted utility discount factor
δt

• equals the unadjusted utility discount factor β if population is constant,

• exceeds β if there is positive population growth, and

• varies with time if population growth is not exponential.

Let ρ > 0 denote the unadjusted utility discount rate, where the relation between β
and ρ is given by

β = 1+ρ.                            (6)

The theoretical presentation of SDU in this section is facilitated by using the utility
discount factor
β , while the numerical results in Section 4 are easier to interpret in
terms of the utility discount rate
ρ. Keeping in mind eq. (6), this should not create
confusion.

Now we turn to the analysis of uncertainty. To handle uncertainty, one can in
principle think of two polar approaches in a situation where there is a probability
distribution over consumption streams.
3 One possibility is first to value each realiza-
tion and then assign probability weights to the different realizations. An alternative
approach is first to determine a certainty equivalent for each generation and then
value the stream of certainty equivalents. When applying SDU to uncertainty, the
choice between these approaches matters for policy evaluation: in the context of
climate change, the possibility of catastrophic consequences is assigned more weight
if the valuation is done first within each realization.

This point can be shown formally under the simplifying assumption that the
utility function
U not only expresses aversion to inequality over time, but also
aversion to risk. By abstracting from population growth and writing
V (u, w) :=
min
{(1 - δ)u +δw, w} for the function that aggregates present utility and future
welfare, it follows from (W.1) that
W (0c) = V (U (c0), W(1c)). Since V is a concave
function of
u and w, it follows from Jensen’s inequality that

E(V(U(co),W(ic))) V(E(U(co)),E(W(ɪe))),

3In the empirical part this corresponds to the empirical distribution of 1000 random draws of a
Latin Hypercube sample.



More intriguing information

1. Luce Irigaray and divine matter
2. BODY LANGUAGE IS OF PARTICULAR IMPORTANCE IN LARGE GROUPS
3. Exchange Rate Uncertainty and Trade Growth - A Comparison of Linear and Nonlinear (Forecasting) Models
4. The name is absent
5. Trade Openness and Volatility
6. The name is absent
7. TWENTY-FIVE YEARS OF RESEARCH ON WOMEN FARMERS IN AFRICA: LESSONS AND IMPLICATIONS FOR AGRICULTURAL RESEARCH INSTITUTIONS; WITH AN ANNOTATED BIBLIOGRAPHY
8. Ability grouping in the secondary school: attitudes of teachers of practically based subjects
9. Reputations, Market Structure, and the Choice of Quality Assurance Systems in the Food Industry
10. Benefits of travel time savings for freight transportation : beyond the costs