References
Acemoglu, D., “Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment and
Politics,” Journal of Comparative Economics, 2003, 31 (4), 620-652.
_ and J. Robinson, “A Theory of Political Transitions,” American Economic Review, 2001,
91 (4), 938-963.
_ and _ , “Economic Backwardness in Political Perspective,” American Political Science Re-
view, 2006, 100 (1), 115-131.
_ , S. Johnson, and J. Robinson, “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An
Empirical Investigation,” American Economic Review, 2001, 91 (5), 1369-1401.
_ , , and _ , “Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-run Growth,” in P. Aghion
and S. Durlauf, eds., Handbook of Economic Growth, North-Holland: Elsevier, 2005.
Alesina, A. and N. Fuchs-Schiindeln, “Good Bye Lenin (or Not?): The Effect of Commu-
nism on People’s Preferences,” American Economic Review, 2007, 97 (4), 1507-1528.
Babetskii, I., L. Boone, and M. Maurel, “Exchange Rate Regimes and Shocks Asymmetry:
The Case of the Accession Countries,” Journal of Comparative Economics, 2004, 32 (3), 212
- 229.
Barro, R. and D. Gordon, “Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in a Natural Rate Model,”
Journal of Political Economy, 1983, 91 (4), 589-610.
Beck, T. and L. Laeven, “Institution Building and Growth in Transition Economies,” Journal
of Economic Growth, 2006, 11 (2), 157-186.
Benjamin, D. and D. Liabson, “Good Policies and Bad Governments: Behavioural Political
Economy,” in “How Humans Behave: Implications for Economics and Economic Policy,”
Vol. 48 of Federal Reserve Bank of Bosten Conference Series FRBB Boston, MA. 2003.
Bruickner, M. and A. Ciccone, “Rain and the Democratic Window of Opportunity,” UPF
Working Paper 1063, 2008.
17