Macroeconomic Interdependence in a Two-Country DSGE Model under Diverging Interest-Rate Rules



3. New Open Economy Macroeconomic Model

two individual goods z, z0 produced within a country σC(z),C(z0) equals θ (CES specification, θ > 1 for an
equilibrium to exist).
9

The total domestic CPI is again a Cobb-Douglas composite of domestic and foreign producer price indexes
(PPIs):

(5)


n 1-n
Pt = Pt,H Pt,F ,

whereupon these subindexes are CES composites of domestic and foreign final goods prices:

Pt,H

Pt,F


Pt(z)1dz


1 -θ


ɪ [1 Pt(z)1 -θdz
1-n n


(6)

(7)


For a derivation of the domestic CPI (5), the domestic PPI for domestic goods (6) as well as the domestic
demand functions for individual and composite domestic goods, which will be introduced below, see
Appendix A.1. The domestic PPI for foreign goods (7), domestic demand curves for individual and
composite foreign goods as well as all foreign indexes can be derived analogously.

Assume that the law of one price holds for consumers across all individual goods at all times:

Pt(z) = StPt (z)z [0, 1],                                                                                   (8)

where S denotes the endogenously determined nominal exchange rate in price quotation (domestic cur-
rency units in terms of foreign currency units).

Thus, as domestic and foreign households are characterized by identical preferences, the law of one price
implies that absolute purchasing power parity (PPP) always holds for the total CPI, even if relative PPP
(stating that
changes in domestic and foreign price levels should be equal in the long run) would be the
more realistic statement (see
Obstfeld/Rogoff 1996, pp. 200-202):

Pt = StPtt .                                                                                          (9)

The demand functions of the representative domestic household for individual domestic C(h) and foreign
goods
C(f) read as follows:

Ct(h)

Ct(f)


Ct,H,


1-n


'P( ( f )
_ Pt,F _


Ct,F,


(10)

(11)


where z = h [0, n] denotes a typical differentiated good z produced at home and z0 = f (n, 1] another
typical differentiated good
z0 produced abroad.

As one can see from equations (10) and (11), demand for individual goods is decreasing in its own price

'σ'"H, Cf |   :


d(HH\ dCH

CF   dCF


,ddCh Ch
d(dCHJ CH


=1,


c (z) ,C (z') |    : =


d Γ C(z)- ]
d LC ( z' )J
d hd C ( z ) i
d[d C ( z' )J


d C ( z )
d C ( z' )
C ( z )
C (z' )


= θ.




More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. ‘Goodwill is not enough’
3. Improvements in medical care and technology and reductions in traffic-related fatalities in Great Britain
4. The name is absent
5. The fundamental determinants of financial integration in the European Union
6. Manufacturing Earnings and Cycles: New Evidence
7. The name is absent
8. CREDIT SCORING, LOAN PRICING, AND FARM BUSINESS PERFORMANCE
9. ISSUES AND PROBLEMS OF IMMEDIATE CONCERN
10. Exchange Rate Uncertainty and Trade Growth - A Comparison of Linear and Nonlinear (Forecasting) Models
11. Who runs the IFIs?
12. Public-private sector pay differentials in a devolved Scotland
13. Impact of Ethanol Production on U.S. and Regional Gasoline Prices and On the Profitability of U.S. Oil Refinery Industry
14. Perceived Market Risks and Strategic Risk Management of Food Manufactures: Empirical Results from the German Brewing Industry
15. Weather Forecasting for Weather Derivatives
16. Eigentumsrechtliche Dezentralisierung und institutioneller Wettbewerb
17. THE AUTONOMOUS SYSTEMS LABORATORY
18. The name is absent
19. Gender and headship in the twenty-first century
20. TOWARD CULTURAL ONCOLOGY: THE EVOLUTIONARY INFORMATION DYNAMICS OF CANCER