Explaining Growth in Dutch Agriculture: Prices, Public R&D, and Technological Change



and Rutten, 1998; cf. Alston, Norton and Pardy (2002) for a similar result for the US). Moreover it
stimulates the development of new innovations, which may partly come from spin-offs of
breakthroughs elsewhere in the Dutch economy or in the international agricultural sphere. As a
consequence the public expenditure on R&D could be well treated as an investment-variable, leading
to the build up of a ‘capital stock’ of innovations and farmer skills. For this reason Figure 1 not only
shows the annual investments in agricultural R&D, but also the accumulated value or the ‘capital
stock’ it creates. It is assumed that new expenditures increase the stock and may have effects lasting
longer than one year. At the same time new investments may create new knowledge and improved
practices, which make part of the old knowledge obsolete. Therefore also a 4% depreciation factor is
applied to the public R&D ‘capital stock’.

------R&D expenditure                ———— Capital stock


Figure 4 Public R&D expenditures and ‘capital’-formation in Dutch agriculture
Source: Based on Roseboom and Rutten, 1998 and own estimates

Model and specification

Output and input price responsiveness in agriculture has been widely analyzed using a dual
(restricted) profit function approach (Chambers, 1988). The impact of public research expenditures on
agricultural output has been analyzed within the context of a primal production function approach (see
for example Fulginiti and Perrin, 1993). In this study a profit function framework which accounts for
R&D expenditures is chosen.

Following Bouchet et al (1989) let the short-run restricted profit function be ∏ = ∏(P,Z,W) ,
where P is a vector of the expected output and variable input prices (P
i: i=1,...,m), Z is a vector of the
quasi-fixed inputs (Zj∙: j=1,...,n), and W is a vector of the fixed inputs and exogenous factors. (Wk:
k=1,.,s). Let R be a vector of market prices of the quasi-fixed inputs (R
j: j=1,.n). At a long-run
optimum, the partial derivatives of the restricted profit function with respect to the quantities of the
quasi-fixed inputs (shadow prices) are equal to their long-run equilibrium market prices:

R>=∂∏° z ( pzi' )

(1)


By solving equations (1) for the optimal Zj’s, the long-run, profit maximizing levels of the quasi-
fixed inputs, Z*=Z*(P,R,W) can be derived.



More intriguing information

1. Bird’s Eye View to Indonesian Mass Conflict Revisiting the Fact of Self-Organized Criticality
2. School Effectiveness in Developing Countries - A Summary of the Research Evidence
3. Heavy Hero or Digital Dummy: multimodal player-avatar relations in FINAL FANTASY 7
4. Global Excess Liquidity and House Prices - A VAR Analysis for OECD Countries
5. The name is absent
6. National curriculum assessment: how to make it better
7. The name is absent
8. Olive Tree Farming in Jaen: Situation With the New Cap and Comparison With the Province Income Per Capita.
9. Self-Help Groups and Income Generation in the Informal Settlements of Nairobi
10. Rent Dissipation in Chartered Recreational Fishing: Inside the Black Box
11. Three Policies to Improve Productivity Growth in Canada
12. The Role of State Trading Enterprises and Their Impact on Agricultural Development and Economic Growth in Developing Countries
13. Survey of Literature on Covered and Uncovered Interest Parities
14. The name is absent
15. Three Strikes and You.re Out: Reply to Cooper and Willis
16. The name is absent
17. The name is absent
18. The name is absent
19. Strategic Investment and Market Integration
20. The English Examining Boards: Their route from independence to government outsourcing agencies