The name is absent



1. Introduction

In this paper we set out an elementary game-theoretic model of conflict between groups based
on individual behavior. We focus on the role of heterogeneity both between and within groups
in explaining conflict. Individuals differ not only in the group they belong to — their “ethnic-
ity” — but also in their wealth and in the radicalism of their commitment to the group’s cause.
The within group heterogeneity in wealths and radicalism is the main novelty of this paper. Be-
sides examining the more standard issue of whether higher heterogeneity across groups leads
to higher conflict, we also study the role of within-group homogeneity. As is now well-known,
both these features have been highlighted in recent literature on the conceptualization and mea-
surement of polarization.1

The model is extremely simple, and is to be regarded more than anything else as a tool to clas-
sify different factors in conflictual situations. But even in this stripped-down form the model
yields some insights, arguing — for instance — that economic inequality
within ethnic groups
rather than
across them is likely to be a potent force in determining the extent of ethnic vio-
lence. This sort of model may therefore be useful, because in spite of the continued attention
to the issue of ethnic/religious conflict analysts appear quite far from a minimal agreement on
its basic driving forces. In his comprehensive survey Horowitz (1998)2 lists up to ten distinct
explanations for social conflict, some substitutes for each other, some complementary. To each
such family of explanations he produces countering facts. This variety of possible causal factors,
while rich, can be at the same time confusing and not easily amenable to empirical falsification.

A first major concern in the analysis of religious/ethnic conflict is to account for the obvi-
ous passion and rage overwelmingly present on either side of the ethnic divide. Writers such
as Horowitz (1985, 1998) and Brewer (1979, 1991 and 1997) have argued that the success of the
group has value
per se, quite independently of the material benefits that the group members
could derive from a victory over the opponent. Horowitz (1998) stresses the role of passion
along with sheer material interest in explaining individual behavior in conflict. In the exercise
that follows, we will let individuals be motivated by group success — conceived of here as the
payoffs from an “ethnic public good” — and we permit these payoffs to vary across individ-
uals as well the direct material components of their well-being. In this sense, we marry the
rational choice tradition with a broadening of the notion of individual motivations, including
non-material, group-defined rewards.

A second goal of this paper is to emphasize the different roles played by economic factors.
Typically, economic wealth plays a double role. The first role is one we do not particularly
emphasize, though we allow for it: wealth determines the stakes in case a victory over the
opponent comes with (possibly partial) expropriation of the opponent’s resources. From this
angle, we should expect that the larger are wealth differences across groups the more likely it is
that conflict will break out. This is the view held by Wintrobe (1995) who views inter-group envy
as a major cause of conflict. In the same vein, Stewart (2002) identifies “horizontal inequality”
across groups — the existence or the perception of an unjustly widening economic gap between
them — as a major source of ethnic conflict.

Two considerations militate against this point of view. First, whether or not inter-group
inequality is conflictual depends crucially on whether the economically
weaker group or the
stronger is the instigator of conflict.3 While we do not pursue this particular thread here, we
follow a complementary line of reasoning by emphasizing a second role played by wealth: that

1See Esteban and Ray (1994) and Duclos, Esteban and Ray (2004) for the notion and measure of polarization and
Esteban and Ray (1999) for the role of polarization among groups in conflict.

2See also his classic, Horowitz (1985).

3Pande and Ray (2003) make this point.



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. The name is absent
3. Psychological Aspects of Market Crashes
4. From Communication to Presence: Cognition, Emotions and Culture towards the Ultimate Communicative Experience. Festschrift in honor of Luigi Anolli
5. Apprenticeships in the UK: from the industrial-relation via market-led and social inclusion models
6. The quick and the dead: when reaction beats intention
7. How much do Educational Outcomes Matter in OECD Countries?
8. HACCP AND MEAT AND POULTRY INSPECTION
9. Thresholds for Employment and Unemployment - a Spatial Analysis of German Regional Labour Markets 1992-2000
10. The name is absent
11. INTERACTION EFFECTS OF PROMOTION, RESEARCH, AND PRICE SUPPORT PROGRAMS FOR U.S. COTTON
12. TWENTY-FIVE YEARS OF RESEARCH ON WOMEN FARMERS IN AFRICA: LESSONS AND IMPLICATIONS FOR AGRICULTURAL RESEARCH INSTITUTIONS; WITH AN ANNOTATED BIBLIOGRAPHY
13. Julkinen T&K-rahoitus ja sen vaikutus yrityksiin - Analyysi metalli- ja elektroniikkateollisuudesta
14. The name is absent
15. Convergence in TFP among Italian Regions - Panel Unit Roots with Heterogeneity and Cross Sectional Dependence
16. The Integration Order of Vector Autoregressive Processes
17. Explaining Growth in Dutch Agriculture: Prices, Public R&D, and Technological Change
18. Pursuit of Competitive Advantages for Entrepreneurship: Development of Enterprise as a Learning Organization. International and Russian Experience
19. RETAIL SALES: DO THEY MEAN REDUCED EXPENDITURES? GERMAN GROCERY EVIDENCE
20. Critical Race Theory and Education: Racism and antiracism in educational theory and praxis David Gillborn*