Crime as a Social Cost of Poverty and Inequality: A Review Focusing on Developing Countries



Crime as a Social Cost of Poverty
and Inequolrty: A Review Focusing
on Developing Countries

F. Bourguignon

instruments. This is a rather delicate task. Some work has been done on
whether ‘prisons pay’ in the US
-see Piehl and diɪulio (1995)-. The
desirability of anti-crime policies like ‘zero tolerance’, ‘three strikes and
you’re out’, ‘fixing broken windows’, which have been very" much debated
in the US, would also have to be analyzed within such a framework17.
However, in most countries, and particularly in developing countries, the
data base necessary to make the corresponding calculation is hardly
available.

From a positive point of view, the endogeneity of expenditures on criminal
justice and police leads to an analysis of crime and its evolution partly
based on the public-decision process behind these expenditures. In times
of rapid urban expansion, all public infrastructures, including those linked
to crime prevention and sanction, tend to lag behind the needs of the
population, which should imply some increase in criminality, other things
being the same. An increased demand for crime deterrence is then
expressed by the civil society, part of which will be effectively met. How
much essentially depends on public-spending decision mechanisms and
possibly on the social structure of urban society. It is interesting to note
that through this political economy of spending on crime deterrence,
economic and social inequality may in effect play an indirect role on crime,
on top of the direct incentives they represent for criminals. It is not clear,
however, whether more inequality should lead to a larger anti-crime budget
or the opposite. Not only the structure of society and the political weight
of the various classes is important here, but also the social geography of
the city and the technology of crime prevention. One may well
imagine
instances where the public-decision mechanism about spending on crime
deterrence lead to rich neighborhoods and business districts being heavily
protected and relatively little being spent in poor neighborhoods and on
more general crime disincentives. That in many societies not only criminals
but also victims are found predominantly among disadvantaged social
groups maybe explained by such a mechanism. Ofeoursc, a less inequitable
outcome may also be possible depending on the social characteristics of
the city18.

17 See Kclling and Coles (1996). See also the recent book review by Massing (1998).
1*i This is partly studied in Bourguignon (1998),

76



More intriguing information

1. Innovation Trajectories in Honduras’ Coffee Value Chain. Public and Private Influence on the Use of New Knowledge and Technology among Coffee Growers
2. The Folklore of Sorting Algorithms
3. The name is absent
4. Female Empowerment: Impact of a Commitment Savings Product in the Philippines
5. Imperfect competition and congestion in the City
6. Uncertain Productivity Growth and the Choice between FDI and Export
7. The name is absent
8. Structural Conservation Practices in U.S. Corn Production: Evidence on Environmental Stewardship by Program Participants and Non-Participants
9. The name is absent
10. CGE modelling of the resources boom in Indonesia and Australia using TERM
11. The name is absent
12. Food Prices and Overweight Patterns in Italy
13. ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY: THE LEGISLATIVE AND REGULATORY AGENDA
14. The name is absent
15. The name is absent
16. Neural Network Modelling of Constrained Spatial Interaction Flows
17. Return Predictability and Stock Market Crashes in a Simple Rational Expectations Model
18. The name is absent
19. Gianluigi Zenti, President, Academia Barilla SpA - The Changing Consumer: Demanding but Predictable
20. AGRIBUSINESS EXECUTIVE EDUCATION AND KNOWLEDGE EXCHANGE: NEW MECHANISMS OF KNOWLEDGE MANAGEMENT INVOLVING THE UNIVERSITY, PRIVATE FIRM STAKEHOLDERS AND PUBLIC SECTOR