The Nobel Memorial Prize for Robert F. Engle



Constructing “Raw” Yields

Let us first fix ideas and establish notation by introducing three key theoretical constructs and the
relationships among them: the discount curve, the forward curve, and the yield curve. Let
Pt (τ) denote
the price of a τ-period discount bond, i.e., the present value at time t of $1 receivable τ periods ahead, and
let
yt (τ) denote its continuously-compounded zero-coupon nominal yield to maturity. From the yield
curve we obtain the discount curve,

PtW = e",'f",

and from the discount curve we obtain the instantaneous (nominal) forward rate curve,
ft(τ) = PP ((τ)/ Pt (τ).

The relationship between the yield to maturity and the forward rate is therefore

y( (τ) = 1
τ
0

which implies that the zero-coupon yield is an equally-weighed average of forward rates. Given the yield
curve or forward curve, we can price any coupon bond as the sum of the present values of future coupon
and principal payments.

In practice, yield curves, discount curves and forward curves are not observed. Instead, they
must be estimated from observed bond prices. Two popular approaches to constructing yields proceed by
estimating a smooth discount curve and then converting to yields at the relevant maturities via the above
formulae. The first discount-curve approach to yield construction is due to McCulloch (1975) and
McCulloch and Kwon (1993), who model the discount curve with a cubic spline. The fitted discount
curve, however, diverges at long maturities instead of converging to zero. Hence such curves provide a
poor fit to yield curves that are flat or have a flat long end, which requires an exponentially decreasing
discount function.

A second discount-curve approach to yield construction is due to Vasicek and Fong (1982), who
fit exponential splines to the discount curve, using a negative transformation of maturity instead of
maturity itself, which ensures that the forward rates and zero-coupon yields converge to a fixed limit as
maturity increases. Hence the Vasicek-Fong model is more successful at fitting yield curves with flat



More intriguing information

1. Popular Conceptions of Nationhood in Old and New European
2. TECHNOLOGY AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT: THE CASE OF PATENTS AND FIRM LOCATION IN THE SPANISH MEDICAL INSTRUMENTS INDUSTRY.
3. The name is absent
4. Contribution of Economics to Design of Sustainable Cattle Breeding Programs in Eastern Africa: A Choice Experiment Approach
5. Lending to Agribusinesses in Zambia
6. The Tangible Contribution of R&D Spending Foreign-Owned Plants to a Host Region: a Plant Level Study of the Irish Manufacturing Sector (1980-1996)
7. The name is absent
8. The name is absent
9. The name is absent
10. Confusion and Reinforcement Learning in Experimental Public Goods Games
11. The name is absent
12. The name is absent
13. A THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK FOR EVALUATING SOCIAL WELFARE EFFECTS OF NEW AGRICULTURAL TECHNOLOGY
14. Trade Openness and Volatility
15. Estimating the Economic Value of Specific Characteristics Associated with Angus Bulls Sold at Auction
16. Investment and Interest Rate Policy in the Open Economy
17. Making International Human Rights Protection More Effective: A Rational-Choice Approach to the Effectiveness of Ius Standi Provisions
18. The name is absent
19. THE ECONOMICS OF COMPETITION IN HEALTH INSURANCE- THE IRISH CASE STUDY.
20. The name is absent