Mean Variance Optimization of Non-Linear Systems and Worst-case Analysis



reserves internally, which changes how they insure against liquidity risk. Second, this ‘in-
ternal money market’ gives them a financing cost advantage, whose size is endogenously
determined. Third, the merged banks may enjoy cost efficiencies that reduce their lending
costs to
β, where β < 1. Fourth, they gain market power in setting loan rates. All these
factors affect banks’ equilibrium balance sheets and, in turn, the demand and supply of
liquidity. We begin with discussing how the merger modifies banks’ reserve holdings, and
then we turn to its effects on costs and loan market competition.

4.1 Internal Money Market and Choice of Reserves

We note first that the merger does not affect the optimal reserve-deposit ratio of the N - 2
competitors. As they have the same cost structure as in the status quo, they still choose
their reserve-deposit ratios according to (10), i.e.,
kc = ksq. This implies also that they have
the same per-unit financing costs
r/rlrD as in the status quo (from Proposition 1).

By contrast, the merged banks, say bank 1 and bank 2, choose a different reserve-deposit
ratio, because the merger modifies the distribution of their liquidity shocks and also allows
them to pool their reserves to meet the total demand for liquidity. Thus, as long as the
two banks continue to raise deposits in two separate regions, the merger leaves room for
an
internal money market in which they can reshuffle reserves according to their respective
needs. For simplicity, we assume a ‘perfect’ internal money market, so that exchanging
reserves internally involves no cost, but all qualitative results go through as long as the
internal money market is less costly than the interbank one. Proceeding in this way is
motivated by recent empirical research suggesting that internal capital markets function
relatively efficiently (see, e.g., Graham et al., 2002; Houston et al.,1997; and Campello,
2002)
.

Let xm = δ1D1 + δ2D2 be the total demand for liquidity of the merged banks at date
1,
Rm = R1 + R2 be their total reserves and Dm = D1 + D2 be their total deposits. The

combined profits of the merged banks are then given by

Πm


(r1L


- βc)L1 + (r2L


Dm
βc)L2 -

Rm


rI (xm


Rm )f (xm )dxm


(11)


-rD [D1(1 - E(δ1)) + D2(1 - E(δ2))] .

The first two terms in (11) represent the combined profits from the loan market, with β
reflecting potential efficiency gains in the form of reduced loan lending costs, the third term

14



More intriguing information

1. The Employment Impact of Differences in Dmand and Production
2. The name is absent
3. The name is absent
4. The name is absent
5. Assessing Economic Complexity with Input-Output Based Measures
6. The name is absent
7. The Effects of Reforming the Chinese Dual-Track Price System
8. The name is absent
9. The Nobel Memorial Prize for Robert F. Engle
10. Confusion and Reinforcement Learning in Experimental Public Goods Games
11. The name is absent
12. How do investors' expectations drive asset prices?
13. Design and investigation of scalable multicast recursive protocols for wired and wireless ad hoc networks
14. The name is absent
15. Evolving robust and specialized car racing skills
16. Dual Track Reforms: With and Without Losers
17. Sustainability of economic development and governance patterns in water management - an overview on the reorganisation of public utilities in Campania, Italy, under EU Framework Directive in the field of water policy (2000/60/CE)
18. Implementation of a 3GPP LTE Turbo Decoder Accelerator on GPU
19. The Context of Sense and Sensibility
20. The name is absent