4.891 (1.599) |
-0.075 (-1.220) |
0.595 (8.383)*** |
-0.160 (-1.458) |
0.008 |
0.993 |
0.851 |
0.070 | |
6.114 |
-0.075 |
0.595 |
-0.219 |
0.007 |
0.993 |
0.851 |
0.070 | |
(1.582) |
(-1.211) |
(8.382)*** |
(-1.452) |
(0.661) |
*** Statistically significant at 1% level, ** Statistically significant at 5% level, * Statistically significant at 10% level
Table 18 Infrastructure effects on the equilibrium number of firms (augmented regression): Athens panel
for sectors, 1982-1991
Dependent Variable: ln of Number of Manufacturing Establishments_____________________________________________________________________________
Constant 1.778 |
lnK 0.205 |
lnL 0.525 |
lnG(total) -0.234 |
lnG(prod) |
lnG(social) |
time |
Adjust. |
SSE 1.783 |
SE 0.103 |
3.008 |
0.203 |
0.528 |
-0.292 |
-0.006 |
0.988 |
1.768 |
0.103 | ||
(0.739) |
(2.839)*** |
(8.113)*** |
(-1.742)* |
(-0.432) | |||||
-2.868 |
0.210 |
0.521 |
-0.040 |
-0.026 |
0.987 |
1.800 |
0.104 | ||
(-0.629) |
(2.917)*** |
(7.948)*** |
(-0.208) |
(-1.830)* |
*** Statistically significant at 1% level, ** Statistically significant at 5% level, * Statistically significant at 10% level
Table 19 Infrastructure effects on the equilibrium number of firms (augmented regression): Rest of
Greece panel for sectors, 1982-1991
Dependent Variable: ln of Number of Manufacturing Establishments
Constant 5.147 |
lnK -0.082 |
lnL 0.585 |
lnG(total) -0.186 |
lnG(prod) |
lnG(social) |
time |
Adjust. |
SSE 1.208 |
SE 0.083 |
4.667 |
-0.081 |
0.585 |
-0.169 |
0.022 |
0.991 |
1.208 |
0.083 | ||
(1.360) |
(-1.283) |
(8.500)*** |
(-1.295) |
(1.570) | |||||
6.520 |
-0.082 |
0.585 |
-0.254 |
0.022 |
0.991 |
1.206 |
0.083 | ||
(1.476) |
(-1.296) |
(8.522)*** |
(-1.418) |
(1.702)* |
*** Statistically significant at 1% level, ** Statistically significant at 5% level, * Statistically significant at 10% level
It seems that public infrastructure does not affect the equilibrium number of firms, at least in
this model context. There are, however, examples of other research focused on firm entry and exit in
Greek industrial sector, in which public capital appears to be a significant factor of firm creation.
These results, as well as comments, criticisms and potential extensions of this model are discussed in
the next section.
5 Conclusions
The proliferation of empirical research on the effects of public capital investment on the
private sector of the economy has provided a substantial body of work. This is based mainly on
production function analysis, or alternatively on the duality theory and cost function approach. These
approaches can be useful in assessing the role of infrastructure and can be used as a tool for the
planning of public investment policies. Having said that, there still remains the problem of an
analytical theoretical basis outlining the mechanisms by which public capital generates, or not, these
specific effects. A few models by which these mechanisms can be sketched have recently become
available. But few of them have been empirically tested for any verification or refutation of their
theoretical assumptions.
27
More intriguing information
1. The resources and strategies that 10-11 year old boys use to construct masculinities in the school setting2. El Mercosur y la integración económica global
3. Regionale Wachstumseffekte der GRW-Förderung? Eine räumlich-ökonometrische Analyse auf Basis deutscher Arbeitsmarktregionen
4. The name is absent
5. Mean Variance Optimization of Non-Linear Systems and Worst-case Analysis
6. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
7. Infrastructure Investment in Network Industries: The Role of Incentive Regulation and Regulatory Independence
8. A Rational Analysis of Alternating Search and Reflection Strategies in Problem Solving
9. Input-Output Analysis, Linear Programming and Modified Multipliers
10. THE INTERNATIONAL OUTLOOK FOR U.S. TOBACCO