dependent variable is the logarithm of the number of manufacturing establishments, and the
independent variable is the logarithm of the public infrastructure capital stock. The latter is again
introduced as three forms (total, productive, and social) in each of the four spatial levels of reference.
Again, the regressions have included a constant term, a time trend, and a set of (N-1) dummy
variables capturing the regional or sectoral specific effects (not reported on here due to space
limitations). Thus, the working equation becomes:
nu = Git +1 + uit (42)
(notation as in previous equations)
The results of tables 12 to 15 show that there is no direct impact of public capital on the
number of establishments, as the public capital coefficients are statistically insignificant in all these
regressions. This is true for all spatial levels. However, as Holtz-Eakin and Lovely have argued, there
is the danger that such a regression “fails to control for the resources available to the manufacturing
sector” (1996, p. 120).
Table 12 Infrastructure effects on the equilibrium number of firms (regression based infrastructure and
time): Regional panel for total manufacturing, 1982-1991
Dependent Variable: ln of Number of Manufacturing Establishments |
lnG(social) |
time -0.004 |
Adjust. |
SSE 21.276 |
SE 0.220 | ||
Constant -0.978 (-0.574) |
lnG(total) 0.104 (1.208) |
lnG(prod) | |||||
0.448 |
0.032 |
0.004 |
0.976 |
21.337 |
0.221 | ||
(0.315) |
(0.445) |
(0.374) | |||||
-2.836 |
0.218 |
-0.003 |
0.977 |
20.869 |
0.218 | ||
(-2.291)** |
(3.168)*** |
(-0.582) |
*** Statistically significant at 1% level, ** Statistically significant at 5% level, * Statistically significant at 10% level
Table 13 Infrastructure effects on the equilibrium number of firms (regression based infrastructure and
time): Greece panel for sectors, 1982-1991
Dependent Variable: ln of Number of Manufacturing Establishments |
lnG(social) |
time -0.004 |
Adjust. |
SSE 1.205 |
SE 0.082 | ||
Constant 7.432 |
lnG(total) -0.130 (-0.939) |
lnG(prod) | |||||
7.139 (2.255)** |
-0.120 (-0.937) |
-0.005 (-0.347) |
0.990 |
1.205 |
0.082 | ||
8.053 (1.928)* |
-0.164 (-0.929) |
-0.005 (-0.412) |
0.990 |
1.205 |
0.082 |
*** Statistically significant at 1% level, ** Statistically significant at 5% level, * Statistically significant at 10% level
Table 14 Infrastructure effects on the equilibrium number of firms (regression based infrastructure and Dependent Variable: ln of Number of Manufacturing Establishments Constant lnG(total) lnG(prod) lnG(social) time Adjust. SSE SE trend R2 8.784 -0.212 -0.029 0.979 3.027 0.134 (1.584) (-0.897) (-1.619) | |||||
9.525 |
-0.248 |
-0.025 |
0.979 |
3.018 |
0.134 |
25
More intriguing information
1. The name is absent2. A Unified Model For Developmental Robotics
3. School Effectiveness in Developing Countries - A Summary of the Research Evidence
4. Determinants of Household Health Expenditure: Case of Urban Orissa
5. NATURAL RESOURCE SUPPLY CONSTRAINTS AND REGIONAL ECONOMIC ANALYSIS: A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM APPROACH
6. Palvelujen vienti ja kansainvälistyminen
7. The Trade Effects of MERCOSUR and The Andean Community on U.S. Cotton Exports to CBI countries
8. The name is absent
9. Dementia Care Mapping and Patient-Centred Care in Australian residential homes: An economic evaluation of the CARE Study, CHERE Working Paper 2008/4
10. Does Market Concentration Promote or Reduce New Product Introductions? Evidence from US Food Industry