Unilateral Actions the Case of International Environmental Problems



figure 1. Although total reductions might be increased by a unilateral move, it
does not seem to be a good idea for country
i to engage in unilateral actions, if
its aim of setting a good example will be strategically exploited by other coun-
tries. No rational country will ever find it worthwhile to undertake unilateral
actions under this model.

One shortcoming with Hoel’s approach is that h remains unexplained. It does
not seem to be rational for a country to engage in unilateral actions when it
knows the above relationship. This is why
h cannot be a choice variable in
Hoel’s model. The interesting question remains: Can unilateral actions be ra-
tional (i.e. result from optimising behaviour) if Hoel’s (1991) reaction function
approach is used without conditioning unilateral actions on the presence of non-
choice variables?

We turn now to an examination of the way the costs influence the Nash-
equilibrium. Let
θi be a shifting parameter in the cost function of country i, such
that:

C

(2)


(3)


C1 (qi,θi ) Ci(qi,θi ) for θi > θi for all qi Q1 and ɪ > 0

θ1

In appendix 1, it is shown that

q1- 0 and q2- 0, i,j I
θ1         ∂θ1

The intuition behind (3) is that increased costs in country 1 lead to less reduc-
tions by country 1, which increases the marginal benefit to country 2 (as long as
country 2 does not change its emission). Hence, country 2 will respond by in-
creasing its reduction efforts.

13



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. Knowledge, Innovation and Agglomeration - regionalized multiple indicators and evidence from Brazil
3. The name is absent
4. What Drives the Productive Efficiency of a Firm?: The Importance of Industry, Location, R&D, and Size
5. Public-Private Partnerships in Urban Development in the United States
6. The name is absent
7. References
8. The name is absent
9. Does Competition Increase Economic Efficiency in Swedish County Councils?
10. Altruism and fairness in a public pension system