Thus, (βbw -βbg) converges in probability to zero much faster in CASE 1.2 than in
CASE 1.1. Nonetheless, the Hausman statistic is asymptotically χ2-distributed
in both cases.
CASE 2: We now consider two simple examples in which the time-varying
regressor xit is stationary without trend. Assume:
xit = Θ2,i + Ψ2,t + eit, (21)
where Θ21,i and Ψ21,t are fixed individual-specific and time-specific effects, re-
spectively. Define
P2,1 = limN→∞ nN Pi θ2,i; p2,2 = limN→∞ N ^{ 02^;
q2,1 = limτ→∞ T Pt ψ2,t; q2,2 = limτ→∞ T Pt ψ2,t.
Notice that if the Θ2,i are allowed to vary across different i, the xit become
cross-sectionally heteroskedastic. Similarly to CASE 1, we will demonstrate
that the convergence rates of the between estimator and the Hausman statistic
depend on whether the xit is cross-sectionally heteroskedastic or homogeneous.
CASE 2.1: Assume that the Θ2,i vary across different i; that is, p2,1 -p22,2 6=
0. With this assumption, we can easily show:
plimN,τ →∞ NT Ant |
= |
q2,2 |
- q22,1 + σe2 ; |
ιl^ 1 R plvm∙N,τ →∞ NfBNT |
= |
p2,2 |
- p22,1; |
plimN,τ →∞ nCnt |
= |
0; | |
11^ 1 R plimN →∞ N Hn |
= |
2 |
-N= aNT =⇒ N(0, σV(q2,2 - ql,ι + σe));
√NbNT =⇒ n(0, σU(p2,2 - p2,1));
√1NcNT =⇒ N(0, σUσ2).
With these results, we can show
σ-,'λ σ σ σ2 ʌ , x
√nt(bw - β) =⇒ N 0, ----- v ; (22)
(q2,2 - q22,1 + σe2)
√N(βb - β)=⇒ N ∣0, ---- ]; (23)
(p2,2 - p22,1)
More intriguing information
1. Fortschritte bei der Exportorientierung von Dienstleistungsunternehmen2. Cultural Neuroeconomics of Intertemporal Choice
3. The Impact of Individual Investment Behavior for Retirement Welfare: Evidence from the United States and Germany
4. The name is absent
5. Altruism with Social Roots: An Emerging Literature
6. Foreword: Special Issue on Invasive Species
7. The name is absent
8. Categorial Grammar and Discourse
9. Naïve Bayes vs. Decision Trees vs. Neural Networks in the Classification of Training Web Pages
10. The name is absent