The name is absent



production, Alchian (1950) and Friedman (1953) took an instrumentalist stance towards economics as a
science. Their argumentation holds that, shortly stated, the assumptions of a theory need not be realistic as
long as the hypotheses derived from the theory are helpful in predicting the future.

Ironically, Friedman’s use of the theory of natural selection to defend neoclassical economics has
probably accelerated to development of evolutionary economics as an alternative to neoclassical
economics. Not long after Friedman’s (1953) essay, scholars argued if economic ‘natural selection’
underlies the economy, economic theory should explicitly model the economy as an evolutionary process
rather than implicitly assuming this to be the case (Koopmans 1957; Winter 1964). This position is in line
with realism, as opposed to instrumentalism, in that evolutionary models try to unravel the precise
mechanisms driving change. Put differently, scholars adhering to realism are primarily interested in
understanding the underlying mechanism in society, and only secondarily in prediction (which is
inherently difficult due to the sheer complexity of social and economic life). In this light, the most
important contribution to evolutionary economics has been the seminal work by Nelson and Winter
(1982). They showed that an important part of neoclassical theory can indeed be formally reformulated as
an evolutionary theory of economic change. A core assumption in their work has been that firms are
bounded rational (Simon 1955), and react to their economic environment according to routines rather than
through maximisation of profits. From this, it follows that the competitiveness of firms depends on their
capability to improve their routines through innovation
over time. Put differently, where neoclassical
economics deals with price competition and static efficiency, evolutionary economics deals with
Schumpeterian competition and dynamic efficiency (Schumpeter 1942). This explains why evolutionary
economics is also called neo- or post-Schumpeterian economics (Andersen 1994), and since have focused
on Schumpeterian themes as technological development, industrial organisation, and long-term
macroeconomic growth.

3.2 The mathematics debate

The second debate unites evolutionary scholars with neoclassicals, and differentiates them from
institutional economists. The debate centres around the role of mathematical modelling in economics, or
perhaps more accurately, in social science in general. Where evolutionary and neoclassical economists
frequently formalise ideas in abstract modelling, the majority of institutionalists rejects the use of
modelling, because it does not capture the contextual nature of economic life, and life in general
(Hodgson, 1998; Martin, 2000). This rejection of the use of formal mathematical models is not true for all
proponents of institutional economics. Hodgson (1998) summarised the attitude of institutional
economists toward mathematical modelling as follows: “ ... mathematical and statistical techniques are
recognized as the servants of, rather than the essence of economic theory” (p. 173). In doing so, they
criticise the neo-classical attitude to exclude those factors from their analysis that might be relevant (such
as institutional factors), but cannot be formalised and expressed in mathematical forms within a
maximization-equilibrium framework.

Evolutionary economics, though critical towards the exact assumptions used in neoclassical models,
do not reject the use of mathematical modelling as such. Mistakenly, the use of mathematics has been
confused with an anti-realist modelling. As argued by Maki (1992) on various occasions, abstracting from
specifics by formalising particular economic mechanism does not necessarily imply an instrumentalist
position on models as tools for prediction. Mathematical modelling can also serve a realist program aimed

10



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. A Review of Kuhnian and Lakatosian “Explanations” in Economics
3. Migration and employment status during the turbulent nineties in Sweden
4. The problem of anglophone squint
5. Optimal Vehicle Size, Haulage Length, and the Structure of Transport Costs
6. The name is absent
7. On Evolution of God-Seeking Mind
8. IMPLICATIONS OF CHANGING AID PROGRAMS TO U.S. AGRICULTURE
9. Announcement effects of convertible bond loans versus warrant-bond loans: An empirical analysis for the Dutch market
10. ROBUST CLASSIFICATION WITH CONTEXT-SENSITIVE FEATURES
11. Perceived Market Risks and Strategic Risk Management of Food Manufactures: Empirical Results from the German Brewing Industry
12. Exchange Rate Uncertainty and Trade Growth - A Comparison of Linear and Nonlinear (Forecasting) Models
13. American trade policy towards Sub Saharan Africa –- a meta analysis of AGOA
14. Yield curve analysis
15. The Role of Evidence in Establishing Trust in Repositories
16. Auction Design without Commitment
17. The name is absent
18. The name is absent
19. Mergers and the changing landscape of commercial banking (Part II)
20. Bidding for Envy-Freeness: A Procedural Approach to n-Player Fair Division Problems