The name is absent



coordination allows individual countries to raise more revenue, politicians will
therefore want to spend
all of the increased revenue on expanding public sector
employment, apart from any revenue that may be needed to continue satisfying
the recruitment constraint.
¥

Proof of Proposition 5: Using (2.11) and (2.15), the social welfare function (2.5)
may be written as

SW = αu (W + rk) + (1 a) u (w (r + τ) + rk) + g (a) ,

which may be differentiated to give (using w0 = k and the fact that (1 α) k = k

in symmetric equilibrium):

dSW


= 0 initially

da 0 dW -

+ aug ɪ + ak

dr


kUp. (A.31)


0   Z“}|“{

g0 + ug up

Inserting (4.3) through (4.5) into (A.31) and remembering that ug = up, u0g = u0p

and dW = dw initially, we find by using w = FL that

dSW


μ        u0k

a + εa-1 (1


_

∖2

a)

ε (1 a)2

wa


u0(1 a)2
a2 + ε (1 a)2


+ a — £a + εa (1 — a) ]

(A.32)


Equation (A.32) shows that the welfare gain from tax coordination is proportional

to the initial degree of underprovision of public goods, f g-/u-

1 , as measured


by the deviation from the Samuelson condition which requires g-/u- = 1. From

Proposition 3 we know that equation (3.4) must hold in the initial tax competition
equilibrium. Inserting this expression for
g^u- into (A.32), we finally obtain

dSW


u0(1 a)2
a2 + ε (1 a)2


(⅛ )(


(1 a))


1


> 0.


¥

(A.33)


38




More intriguing information

1. The bank lending channel of monetary policy: identification and estimation using Portuguese micro bank data
2. The ultimate determinants of central bank independence
3. A model-free approach to delta hedging
4. The name is absent
5. The name is absent
6. The name is absent
7. Trade Liberalization, Firm Performance and Labour Market Outcomes in the Developing World: What Can We Learn from Micro-LevelData?
8. The name is absent
9. Second Order Filter Distribution Approximations for Financial Time Series with Extreme Outlier
10. A Pure Test for the Elasticity of Yield Spreads