The name is absent



content4; (ii) a pre-specific change in tariff heading; (iii) a specific phase of the production
process performed within the preferential agreement; (iv) substantial transformation of name and
characteristics. Thus, the rules of origin implemented in practice may severely constrain the
profit maximization choices of firms. The production choices available to an economy with the
less restrictive Assumption 2 rules of origin imposed are equivalent to the original production set
with pre-FTA opportunities preserved. More restrictive rules, such as those that require more
than a specified fraction of value to be added by the exporting country, fail to preserve initial
opportunities and may reduce the effective production set.

Let superscripts 0 and 1 describe the pre- and post-FTA situations, respectively. Assume
that each household
j of country i has preferences that can be represented by a utility function
uj. Consistent with the proof of existence of equilibrium, the income of consumers can be any
continuous function of prices. Here we assume that a particular
fair sharing distribution rule is
used, meaning that it provides consumers with enough income to purchase their pre-agreement
consumption bundle at post agreement prices, plus a non-negative supplement:

eljpifuj1]p1 xlf + θlj ((p1 (yi1 + T1 ) - p1 (yi0 + ^i0))

where ejpz,1,uj,1 ] is the consumer’s expenditure function, θj f 0, and ^j. θj = 1.5 A fair
sharing distribution rule
was used in Grinols (1981), for example, and Grandmont and McFadden
(1972) to prove the existence of competitive equilibrium of Kemp-Wan customs unions and of
Pareto-improving free trade allocations, respectively.

Proposition 2 The fair sharing distribution rule is viable in equilibrium under Assumptions 1
and 2 with transfers across member countries.

Proof. Write the change in welfare for consumer j of member country i = {H,F} under
the distribution rule as
AWj ejp1,uj,1] ejp1,uj,0], where uj’0 and uj’1 represent pre- and
post-FTA utility levels. Then

∑∑ Δ^ = ∑(∑(pM0-4 1.⅛°)))             Terml

i j                 i j                             )

+ ∑ ∣ ∑ θ^j P1 {yi1 yi° J                   Term 2

ij /

+ ∑ I ∑ θj P1 (fi>1 zi,0 I                Term 3     (2)

i j /

4Krueger (1997).

5The sum over j of the right hand side of (2) adds to country i income, p1 (yt,1 + ω + zt,1).



More intriguing information

1. Protocol for Past BP: a randomised controlled trial of different blood pressure targets for people with a history of stroke of transient ischaemic attack (TIA) in primary care
2. The name is absent
3. The Value of Cultural Heritage Sites in Armenia: Evidence From a Travel Cost Method Study
4. The name is absent
5. Trade Liberalization, Firm Performance and Labour Market Outcomes in the Developing World: What Can We Learn from Micro-LevelData?
6. The name is absent
7. Testing Hypotheses in an I(2) Model with Applications to the Persistent Long Swings in the Dmk/$ Rate
8. Innovation and business performance - a provisional multi-regional analysis
9. Long-Term Capital Movements
10. BODY LANGUAGE IS OF PARTICULAR IMPORTANCE IN LARGE GROUPS
11. Review of “The Hesitant Hand: Taming Self-Interest in the History of Economic Ideas”
12. QUEST II. A Multi-Country Business Cycle and Growth Model
13. TRADE NEGOTIATIONS AND THE FUTURE OF AMERICAN AGRICULTURE
14. Pricing American-style Derivatives under the Heston Model Dynamics: A Fast Fourier Transformation in the Geske–Johnson Scheme
15. Growth and Technological Leadership in US Industries: A Spatial Econometric Analysis at the State Level, 1963-1997
16. The magnitude and Cyclical Behavior of Financial Market Frictions
17. Improving Business Cycle Forecasts’ Accuracy - What Can We Learn from Past Errors?
18. SLA RESEARCH ON SELF-DIRECTION: THEORETICAL AND PRACTICAL ISSUES
19. Second Order Filter Distribution Approximations for Financial Time Series with Extreme Outlier
20. The Institutional Determinants of Bilateral Trade Patterns