The name is absent



yitj = β0+ βwlwijt +βblbitj + βkkitj +βeeitj + βmmijt +ωitj +εitj

(7)


where yit is the log of gross output (proxied by sales)24 , kit is the log of the plant's
capital stock,
lwit is the log of hours worked by skilled workers (white), lbit is the log of
hours worked by unskilled workers (blue), and
mit and eit denote log-levels of materials,
and energy (which includes consumption of fuel and electricity). The error term has two
unobserved components,
ωit ,the transmitted productivity components and εit,, the
random noise component. The difference between the two is that
ωit is a state variable,
known by the firm when deciding the amount of input to employ in production25, while
εit is independent with respect to input choices. The correlation between the error
component and inputs leads to the well known simultaneity problem firstly highlighted
by Marschak and Andrews (1944). Estimations that ignore this correlation yield biased
results. This is the case for OLS that, most commonly, overestimate the labour
coefficient and underestimates the capital coefficient.

To overcome this problem we use the Levinshon and Petrin (2003) methodology26. This
approach builds on the work of Olley and Pakes (1996) that proposed the use of
investments as proxy to control for the correlation between the unobserved productivity
shock and capital (assuming that labour and materials are freely available inputs). The
Olley-Pakes procedure can be applied only to plants reporting non-zero investments and
this criteria would require a significant truncation of our sample27. For this reason, as
suggested by Levinshon and Petrin, we use intermediate input demand as proxy. In
particular, we use raw material inputs28 that become a valid proxy when their demand
function is monotonic in firm’s productivity for all levels of capital. Appendix A reports
the details of the Levinshon-Petrin estimation procedure, its implementation and a
description of the variables used in estimations.

24 We did also estimated the value added production function, assuming weak separability on materials.
The TFP estimations did not differ substantially.

25 But not by the econometrician.

26 If the productivity is assumed to be plant specific and time invariant, the simultaneity problem can also
be solved including in the regression firm specific effects (fixed-effect panel estimations). However this
estimator does not fully exploit the cross-sectional variation which, especially in our case, with a short
panel, is a relevant dimension.

27 In the case of the ICS of India, new investments are reported only for 1999 and 2001 and even in those
case there is a high frequency of zero observations.

28 Alternatively also electricity consumption, possibly in physical quantities, can be a good proxy but we
have only data on cost of energy. For a more detailed discussion on the choice of proxies see Appendix A.

14



More intriguing information

1. EMU: some unanswered questions
2. Consumption Behaviour in Zambia: The Link to Poverty Alleviation?
3. The voluntary welfare associations in Germany: An overview
4. A Consistent Nonparametric Test for Causality in Quantile
5. The name is absent
6. Existentialism: a Philosophy of Hope or Despair?
7. Multimedia as a Cognitive Tool
8. The name is absent
9. Visual Perception of Humanoid Movement
10. The name is absent
11. HACCP AND MEAT AND POULTRY INSPECTION
12. The name is absent
13. Climate Policy under Sustainable Discounted Utilitarianism
14. Magnetic Resonance Imaging in patients with ICDs and Pacemakers
15. Non Linear Contracting and Endogenous Buyer Power between Manufacturers and Retailers: Empirical Evidence on Food Retailing in France
16. The name is absent
17. Sector Switching: An Unexplored Dimension of Firm Dynamics in Developing Countries
18. The ultimate determinants of central bank independence
19. Explaining Growth in Dutch Agriculture: Prices, Public R&D, and Technological Change
20. Public infrastructure capital, scale economies and returns to variety