Willingness-to-Pay for Energy Conservation and Free-Ridership on Subsidization – Evidence from Germany



uations are based on simple survey questions that ask the respondents whether
they would have hypothetically reached the same decision in absence of the DSM
program. Due to the nature of these questions, the calculated free rider share
may therefore be susceptible to a hypothetical- or response bias.
1 Malm (1996)
circumvents these difficulties by analyzing the revealed choice of high efficiency
heating system purchases among different clusters of consumers. He derives an
impressive share of 89% of households that would have bought the efficient equip-
ment even in the absence of a subsidy.

The present paper illustrates an alternative approach for quantifying free-
riding by combining revealed preference data with cost estimates derived from
engineering calculations. Our method is similar to Cameron’s (1985) in that nests
are imposed to capture correlation of the utility across alternatives, but, rather
than using the nested logit model, we employ an analog thereof that involves
the specification of an error-components structure (Brownstone and Train 1999).
We additionally allow for heterogeneous preferences by specifying household spe-
cific random parameters, closely following Revelt and Train’s (1998) analysis of
the willingness-to-pay for lower operating costs of household appliances. Our
investigation uncovers a potential free-rider share of up to 50% of the sampled
households, substantially lower than Malm’s (1996) estimates but still sufficiently
high to warrant scrutiny of financial support for renovations.

The paper is outlined as follows. After a brief description of the data, Section
2 discusses the challenges of accommodating unobserved heterogenity in a discrete
choice framework and describes alternative models derived from random utility
theory for addressing them. Section 3 catalogues the empirical results and uses
these to derive household-specific estimates of marginal willingness-to-pay. These
results are used to draw policy implications with respect to free-rider problems
in the context of Germany’s current grants scheme. Section 4 concludes.

1To the extent that program participants feel committed to justify the existence of the DSM
program the bias would yield an underestimation of the true free-rider share.



More intriguing information

1. Improving behaviour classification consistency: a technique from biological taxonomy
2. Der Einfluß der Direktdemokratie auf die Sozialpolitik
3. ISSUES AND PROBLEMS OF IMMEDIATE CONCERN
4. The name is absent
5. The name is absent
6. How we might be able to understand the brain
7. Moffett and rhetoric
8. Cyber-pharmacies and emerging concerns on marketing drugs Online
9. Clinical Teaching and OSCE in Pediatrics
10. Tax Increment Financing for Optimal Open Space Preservation: an Economic Inquiry
11. DISCUSSION: POLICY CONSIDERATIONS OF EMERGING INFORMATION TECHNOLOGIES
12. Climate Policy under Sustainable Discounted Utilitarianism
13. Needing to be ‘in the know’: strategies of subordination used by 10-11 year old school boys
14. Prizes and Patents: Using Market Signals to Provide Incentives for Innovations
15. Estimated Open Economy New Keynesian Phillips Curves for the G7
16. Mergers and the changing landscape of commercial banking (Part II)
17. Survey of Literature on Covered and Uncovered Interest Parities
18. Strengthening civil society from the outside? Donor driven consultation and participation processes in Poverty Reduction Strategies (PRSP): the Bolivian case
19. The name is absent
20. Integrating the Structural Auction Approach and Traditional Measures of Market Power