Table 5 — Determinants of personal income inequality — full sample — OLS and IV estimates
robust standard errors — t-statistics in parentheses - * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; ***
significant at 1%
1 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
5 |
6 |
7 |
8 | |
1st |
1st | |||||||
OLS |
OLS |
OLS |
IV |
IV |
IV |
differen differen | ||
labour share at market price |
0.229 |
-0.297 |
-0.365 |
-0.261 |
-0.365 |
-1.345 |
-0.141 |
-0.134 |
[2.94]** |
[2.81]** | |||||||
[1.90]* |
[4.19]*** |
[3.37]*** |
[0.33] |
[2.03]** |
[3.58]*** |
* |
* | |
extended p90∕p10 decile | ||||||||
ratio |
-1.219 |
4.212 |
5.145 |
0.973 |
17.942 |
26.848 |
0.745 |
0.697 |
[2.51]** |
[3.99]*** |
[3.71]*** |
[0.34] |
[4.52]*** |
[4.14]*** |
[1.69]* |
[1.58] | |
unemployment rate |
-0.697 |
0.021 |
0.033 |
-2.679 |
0.784 |
1.138 |
0.029 |
0.025 |
[6.11]*** |
[0.28] |
[0.31] |
[2.61]*** |
[2.42]** |
[2.45]** |
[0.56] |
[0.48] | |
unemployment benefit |
-8.52 |
-21.6 |
-23.398 |
2.284 |
-17.328 |
-11.079 |
0.124 |
1.953 |
[3.45]*** |
[5.47]*** |
[6.45]*** |
[0.26] |
[3.98]*** |
[1.73]* |
[0.03] |
[0.42] | |
time trend |
0.038 |
0.091 |
0.636 |
-0.222 |
-0.423 | |||
[1.02] |
[1.39] |
[3.67]*** |
[2.46]** |
[2.62]*** | ||||
Constant |
yes |
yes |
yes |
yes |
yes |
yes |
yes |
yes |
Country fixed effects |
yes |
yes |
yes |
yes |
yes |
yes | ||
Year fixed effects |
yes |
yes | ||||||
Observations |
210 |
210 |
210 |
210 |
210 |
210 |
202 |
202 |
R2 |
0.51 |
0.93 |
0.94 |
0.12 |
0.87 |
0.79 |
0.05 |
0.15 |
Sargan test (p-value) |
0.05 |
0.07 |
0.80 |
Endogenous variables: labour share, unemployment rate, p90/p10.
Instruments: (log)capital×worker, tax wedge, years of education, minimum wage, bargaining coordination.
Our preferred specification, in terms of sign, significance and size of the effects, is the 5th column
of table 5. Evaluated at sample means, the estimated elasticity of personal income inequality with respect
to the labour share is equal to —0.61, which implies that reducing the labour share by one standard
deviation would raise the Gini coefficient by 2.47 points. The estimated elasticity with respect to the wage
differential is greater, reaching the value 1.63: increasing the decile ratio by one standard deviation would
raise the Gini coefficient by 1.27 Gini points. The elasticities with respect to the unemployment benefit
and the unemployment rate are much lower, respectively 0.12 and 0.14.
The results are basically unchanged when we computed quinquennial averages of the data, when
we restrict the data to the subsample of countries for which we have longer time series, and when we use
the labour share measure adjusted for self-employment (details available from the authors). On the
contrary, when we use the alternative series for income inequality, the labour share is less significant, with
a coefficient that is half in size. The wage differential and the unemployment subsidy are still highly
significant, with coefficients of similar sizes, while the unemployment rate is totally insignificant.
Table 6. — Determinants of personal income inequality — 3SLS regressions
Absolute value of z statistics in brackets - * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%
20
More intriguing information
1. INTERACTION EFFECTS OF PROMOTION, RESEARCH, AND PRICE SUPPORT PROGRAMS FOR U.S. COTTON2. Computing optimal sampling designs for two-stage studies
3. Globalization, Divergence and Stagnation
4. Factores de alteração da composição da Despesa Pública: o caso norte-americano
5. Bargaining Power and Equilibrium Consumption
6. Concerns for Equity and the Optimal Co-Payments for Publicly Provided Health Care
7. If our brains were simple, we would be too simple to understand them.
8. The Triangular Relationship between the Commission, NRAs and National Courts Revisited
9. Subduing High Inflation in Romania. How to Better Monetary and Exchange Rate Mechanisms?
10. ¿Por qué se privatizan servicios en los municipios (pequeños)? Evidencia empírica sobre residuos sólidos y agua.