The name is absent



1. Introduction

Recent empirical research by economists has demonstrated that electoral rules
exert a strong influence on fiscal policy: majoritarian elections are associated with
smaller government spending, smaller budget deficits and smaller welfare states,
compared to proportional elections. Details of electoral rules seem to matter for
corruption and effectiveness in government service provision, better performance
being associated with larger electoral districts, and with individual rather than
party-list ballots.1

For many years, political scientists have stressed the strong influence of elec-
toral rules on the party structure: majoritarian elections are more likely to lead
to a two-party system, while proportional elections often produce fragmentation
of political parties. Moreover, these implications for party structure naturally
spill over to the formation of governments: single-party majority governments
are more common when parties are few, and coalition (or single-party minority)
governments are the norm when parties are many.2

It is a plausible conjecture that these correlations in the data reflect a common
causal chain. Proportional elections raise the number of parties in the legisla-
ture. This raises the incidence of coalition governments, and thereby increases
the likelihood of higher government spending, because policymaking under such
governments is plagued by the so-called common-pool problem.

Despite its plausibility, this conjecture has not really been carefully studied,
neither theoretically nor empirically. One reason may be that the suggested causal
chain is quite complex. Rather than studying the entire chain, researchers have
thus focused on only one or two of its links. Another reason for the lack of encom-
passing research may be that the issues fall in the cracks between two disciplines.
Political scientists have studied the political consequences of alternative electoral
rules and neglected their economic repercussions whereas economists have focused
on their economic effects in simplified political settings where party structures and
types of government are exogenous or play no significant role.3 The goal of this

1 See, in particular, Milesi-Ferretti, Perotti and Rostagno, 2002, Persson and Tabellini 2003,
2004 and Persson, Tabellini and Trebbi, 2003.

2 See, for instance, Laver and Schofield, 1990, Lijphart, 1984, 1994, 1999, Powell, 1982, 2000,
and Taagepera and Shugart, 1989.

3 Thus Cox (1990, 1997) focused on the link between electoral rules and the number of candi-
dates or parties while neglecting government formation and policy; Austen-Smith (2000) studies
taxation and government formation under alternative electoral rules, but takes party structures
as exogenous; Baron and Diermeier (2001) study government formation and policymaking under



More intriguing information

1. Short Term Memory May Be the Depletion of the Readily Releasable Pool of Presynaptic Neurotransmitter Vesicles
2. Multifunctionality of Agriculture: An Inquiry Into the Complementarity Between Landscape Preservation and Food Security
3. Skill and work experience in the European knowledge economy
4. Behavior-Based Early Language Development on a Humanoid Robot
5. A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing (new title: Truly Costly Sequential Search and Oligopolistic Pricing,)
6. Tariff Escalation and Invasive Species Risk
7. A Unified Model For Developmental Robotics
8. Making International Human Rights Protection More Effective: A Rational-Choice Approach to the Effectiveness of Ius Standi Provisions
9. Testing for One-Factor Models versus Stochastic Volatility Models
10. Imputing Dairy Producers' Quota Discount Rate Using the Individual Export Milk Program in Quebec