Volunteering and the Strategic Value of Ignorance



A.7 Proof of Corollary 1

Part (i) follows from Lemma 5(iii). For part (ii), the threshold T is larger than c/2
if and only if the value of information is negative as
T approaches c/2. Moreover,
Vi1 may even be negative for all T. Note that c/2 ClnpH ol/2ol InpH, and
for small
pH, we have ol/2ol lnpH oh/2. With monotonicity of (16), it follows
that, for all
T (ol/2,oh/2), V)j is smaller than

_                    Pn              1_ cH            1 си

lim V/ (T ) = cL —(ohcl) e2 2cr + рн ce 2 + 2c
T ch/2                   2

which is negative for small pH since the second and the third term approach zero if
pH0. For intermediate values of pH, we have T (c/2, oh/2).

A.8 Proof of Proposition 2

Suppose that i remains uninformed and j acquires information. If T < c/2, i’s

expected payoff is strictly higher than j,s expected payoff (compare the first row in

(6) to the first row in (7)).


Thus, if T < min {c/2,t},

in the equilibrium of the


game of sequential information acquisition, the first mover remains uninformed.

If T > c/2 and in case (N, I) the mixed strategy equilibrium is selected, by
continuity of the expected payoffs,
E (π) E (πj) also holds for T = c/2 + δ, δ > 0
sufficiently small (compare the second rows in (6) and (7)). As
T c/2 clnpH,
the payoff of the uninformed player
i approaches υ — C, while the informed player j
gets strictly more than v — C.26 The difference in payoffs E (πj) E (π) is strictly
increasing in
T, and there is a critical value Ts where E (πj) = E (πi). Depending
on the parameters of the model,
Ts can be smaller or larger than the threshold T
for information acquisition. If Ts T, in all equilibria where one player chooses
to remain uninformed, this will be the first mover. If
Ts < T, there can also be
equilibria of the game with sequential information acquisition where the first mover
chooses to acquire information and the second mover remains uninformed.27

26By choosing qjL (0) = 1 and qjH (T) = 1, j can ensure a payoff of at least υ Plc^
Ph (ch/2 + T), which is strictly larger than υ c; thus, his equilibrium payoff cannot be smaller.

27This is the case, for instance, if ¾ = 2, ch = 10, and рн = 0.3. There, in case (N, I),

34



More intriguing information

1. Sex differences in the structure and stability of children’s playground social networks and their overlap with friendship relations
2. Legal Minimum Wages and the Wages of Formal and Informal Sector Workers in Costa Rica
3. THE UNCERTAIN FUTURE OF THE MEXICAN MARKET FOR U.S. COTTON: IMPACT OF THE ELIMINATION OF TEXTILE AND CLOTHING QUOTAS
4. The demand for urban transport: An application of discrete choice model for Cadiz
5. The name is absent
6. Magnetic Resonance Imaging in patients with ICDs and Pacemakers
7. The name is absent
8. Implementation of the Ordinal Shapley Value for a three-agent economy
9. Pass-through of external shocks along the pricing chain: A panel estimation approach for the euro area
10. Natural Resources: Curse or Blessing?