Insecure Property Rights and Growth: The Roles of Appropriation Costs, Wealth Effects, and Heterogeneity



Because of βH (R — ρ)/n (see lemma 6) and κ < κ it follows that all costate trajectories are
constant and non-negative. The Lagrange multiplier
ν is defined by

ν(t)=


( κ — κ )[ ρ — R +( n — 1) вн ] — γ ( ρ — r ) κ
ρ — R
+ H

Because of lemma 6) and (24) we have ν(t) 0. Using these definitions and (6), it is straight-
forward to verify (25)-(29). Condition (30) holds because of
xi (t)=βHz(t).

Defining gH by gH = R — nβH , it follows from lemma 6) that gH . The transversality
condition (31) can now be verified in exactly the same way as in the proof of theorem 1.
Finally, we have to show that the application of the strategy
φi implies that z(t), yi (t), xi (t),
and
ci (t) remain non-negative for all t. Because βH >γqn has been assumed, this property can
be verified in essentially the same way as in the proof of theorem 1. This completes the proof
of the theorem.
<ι

If the assumptions of theorem 1 and βH ≥ βn hold, then the condition βH >γqn required in
theorem 3 is satisfied. This follows trivially from lemma 1. Moreover, condition (24) is true
provided that
βH is sufficiently large. The assumptions of theorem 3 are therefore satisfied
whenever those of theorem 1 hold and when
βH is sufficiently large. It follows that in this case
the pessimistic equilibrium from theorem 3 and the interior equilibrium from theorem 1 coexist.
The equilibrium stated in theorem 3 does not exist if extraction intensities are not bounded
above, that is, if the constraint (23) is missing. If one would introduce a similar lower bound,
that is a constraint of the form
xi (t) ≥ βLz(t), then it would be possible to derive also an
optimistic equilibrium, in which all players extract with intensity
βL . The structure of the
equilibrium strategies in this case would be much more complicated because of the co-existence
of the constraints
xi(t) ≥ βLz(t) and yi (t) 0. In particular, we believe that the strategies
of player
i in any Markov-perfect Nash equilibrium would have to depend non-trivially on all
private asset stocks and not only on the own private asset holdings yi.6 We therefore leave the
characterization of the optimistic equilibrium for a separate paper.

6 Concluding remarks

In this paper, we have shown that new insights can be gained by adding appropriation costs and
wealth effects to the model developed by Tornell and Velasco [11] and Tornell and Lane [10].
A number of testable implications have been derived. For example, countries where powerful
groups have equal appropriation costs have higher growth rates than countries where powerful
groups have unequal costs. Furthermore, an increase in the cost of money laundering reduces
growth.

Our model can be extended in several directions. One may suppose that agents care about both
relative wealth and absolute wealth. This would make the status-seeking motive for the agents

6Tornell and Velasco [11] characterize optimistic equilibria in a model without non-negativity constraints on
private asset holdings.

16



More intriguing information

1. The Cost of Food Safety Technologies in the Meat and Poultry Industries.
2. Spatial Aggregation and Weather Risk Management
3. The Provisions on Geographical Indications in the TRIPS Agreement
4. Fiscal Sustainability Across Government Tiers
5. Demographic Features, Beliefs And Socio-Psychological Impact Of Acne Vulgaris Among Its Sufferers In Two Towns In Nigeria
6. The Structure Performance Hypothesis and The Efficient Structure Performance Hypothesis-Revisited: The Case of Agribusiness Commodity and Food Products Truck Carriers in the South
7. The name is absent
8. Neighborhood Effects, Public Housing and Unemployment in France
9. BEN CHOI & YANBING CHEN
10. The name is absent