Bargaining Power and Equilibrium Consumption



equilibrium price system is

p = (2(1 - α) ,1);

the equilibrium consumption bundles are c0 = (α, 1 /2), cɜ = (1 — α, 1 /2).

Now we are prepared to consider the case of three individuals, labelled i = 1, 2, 3.
Consumers 1 and 2 form the two-person household
h. In this household, consumer
1 has bargaining power
α and consumer 2 has bargaining power 1 - α. Consumer 3
constitutes the single household
k . We are going to scrutinize several representative
examples which are almost exhaustive in that they exhibit three possible allocative
responses to a shift of bargaining power within the two-person household:

(a) Only one member is affected.

(b) The two members are affected in opposite ways.

(c) Both members are affected in the same way.

The examples differ only in individual consumer preferences. The analysis suggests
that less substitutability leads to more drastic price effects. We start with the following
example of case (a).

Example 1.

Here consumer 1 benefits from more bargaining power, to the detriment of consumer
3 while consumer 2 is unaffected. Household
h is endowed with ωh = (1, 0). Its two
members,
i = 1, 2 have utility representations

u1(x1, y1) = x1 and u2(x2, y2) = y2.

The household maximizes

Sh = u1αu12 = x1αy21, 0 < α < 1.

15



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. Integration, Regional Specialization and Growth Differentials in EU Acceding Countries: Evidence from Hungary
3. The name is absent
4. Momentum in Australian Stock Returns: An Update
5. The name is absent
6. Ruptures in the probability scale. Calculation of ruptures’ values
7. ‘Goodwill is not enough’
8. Education Responses to Climate Change and Quality: Two Parts of the Same Agenda?
9. The Structure Performance Hypothesis and The Efficient Structure Performance Hypothesis-Revisited: The Case of Agribusiness Commodity and Food Products Truck Carriers in the South
10. Backpropagation Artificial Neural Network To Detect Hyperthermic Seizures In Rats