30
20
10
À. ---- CEEC
K ' ---Kazakhstan
K K ....... Kyrgyz Republic
---Tajikistan
--Turkmenistan
1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006
Year
Source: IMF (2008).
Fig. 6: Exchange Rate Volatility 1995 - 2006
in year t respectively. The minimum volatility is chosen in order to identify the manipulated,
policy relevant exchange rate. Annual figures are calculated from monthly data for each year.
Figure 6 shows that the CEECs have constantly kept their exchange rate volatilities at very
low levels while most Central Asian countries show higher volatility between 1995 and the year
2000. However, after that, Kazakhstan, the Kyrgyz Republic, and Tajikistan have converged to
CEEC levels in terms of volatility. Turkmenistan and Uzbekistan show higher volatility even
after 2000, which maybe is a result of their poor institutional performance. Thus, credibility in
economic policy making can be crucial in avoiding speculative attacks on the country’s currency
or unnecessarily high exchange rate volatility which also harms external trade and long-term
capital flows.
While the incentive of financial openness in combination with fixed exchange rate regimes
consists in preventing an economic crisis, economic crises themselves can have a positive effect
in the long-run despite painful short-run effects. As already discussed in the previous section,
preferences are often shaped by historical events. Periods of systematic instability can shift
preferences in favour of better regulations among the population and policy makers and open
a window of opportunity for reforms as they reveal weaknesses in institutional arrangements
(Acemoglu and Robinson, 2001; Briickner and Ciccone, 2008). In the aftermath of the crisis
agents may have a higher willingness to reform and prefer better institutions in order to avoid
13