Imitation in location choice



Whenever y is linear in x 1, then y% → y^ as θ2 0. The reason for this is that Firm
2 receives an undistorted version of Firm 1’s private signal while acquiring no private
information of its own, which implies that Firm 2 must have the same expectation of
a and consequently choose the same location as Firm 1.

After substituting (3) into (1), the first-order condition for θ1 is:

dE[ax 1; θ 1]    var(ax 1; θ 1)   ∂C(θ 1)

2( y1 - E[ alx 1; θ1]) -g^---∂el---∂θΓ = 0        (6)

but because the global solution for y in (5) makes the first term in parentheses
on the left-hand side of (6) uniformly zero, this first-order condition simplifies to
dvaraxl;θ 1 ) = d(ɪ). This requires that Firm 1 choose θ 1 to set the marginal
reduction in conditional variance of
a    equal to the marginal cost of information. A

solution to the first-order condition for θ1 may not always exist and, even when it
does, it may not correspond to a global maximum. The boundary values,
θ1 =0and
θ1 = 1, must also be checked. The choice θ1 = 0 maximizes expected profit when
information is too expensive to justify its acquisition at any level, in which case Firm 1
locates at the unconditional mean,
y 1 = μa, and achieves expected profit π0 — σ02. The
choice
θ1 = 1 represents cases where Firm 1 acquires maximally precise information,
implying that var(
αx 1; θ 1) θ 1=1 = 0, and profit π0 — C(1), which is certain in this case
rather than expected.

Given the real-world policy problems associated with the hypothesis of imitation
causing inefficient spatial agglomerations that fail to utilize profitable opportunities
elsewhere, the most interesting case to consider is when Firm 1 acquires information
and Firm 2 does not:
θ1 > 0andθ2 = 0, referred to as absolute imitation. One seeks to
identify the conditions under which imitation of this kind is consistent with expected-
profit maximization. Thus, it is assumed that the global maximizer
θ1 lies on the strict
interior of the unit interval: that is,
π 1(E[ax 1; θ]↑~) > max0 — σa0 — C(1)}.2
2 A sufficient but not necessary condition for existence of an interior solution for θ1 is that the conditional variance



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. DURABLE CONSUMPTION AS A STATUS GOOD: A STUDY OF NEOCLASSICAL CASES
3. The name is absent
4. Understanding the (relative) fall and rise of construction wages
5. Testing Panel Data Regression Models with Spatial Error Correlation
6. A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing (new title: Truly Costly Sequential Search and Oligopolistic Pricing,)
7. A MARKOVIAN APPROXIMATED SOLUTION TO A PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT PROBLEM
8. Regional dynamics in mountain areas and the need for integrated policies
9. Incorporating global skills within UK higher education of engineers
10. Applications of Evolutionary Economic Geography