Imitation in location choice



Whenever y is linear in x 1, then y% → y^ as θ2 0. The reason for this is that Firm
2 receives an undistorted version of Firm 1’s private signal while acquiring no private
information of its own, which implies that Firm 2 must have the same expectation of
a and consequently choose the same location as Firm 1.

After substituting (3) into (1), the first-order condition for θ1 is:

dE[ax 1; θ 1]    var(ax 1; θ 1)   ∂C(θ 1)

2( y1 - E[ alx 1; θ1]) -g^---∂el---∂θΓ = 0        (6)

but because the global solution for y in (5) makes the first term in parentheses
on the left-hand side of (6) uniformly zero, this first-order condition simplifies to
dvaraxl;θ 1 ) = d(ɪ). This requires that Firm 1 choose θ 1 to set the marginal
reduction in conditional variance of
a    equal to the marginal cost of information. A

solution to the first-order condition for θ1 may not always exist and, even when it
does, it may not correspond to a global maximum. The boundary values,
θ1 =0and
θ1 = 1, must also be checked. The choice θ1 = 0 maximizes expected profit when
information is too expensive to justify its acquisition at any level, in which case Firm 1
locates at the unconditional mean,
y 1 = μa, and achieves expected profit π0 — σ02. The
choice
θ1 = 1 represents cases where Firm 1 acquires maximally precise information,
implying that var(
αx 1; θ 1) θ 1=1 = 0, and profit π0 — C(1), which is certain in this case
rather than expected.

Given the real-world policy problems associated with the hypothesis of imitation
causing inefficient spatial agglomerations that fail to utilize profitable opportunities
elsewhere, the most interesting case to consider is when Firm 1 acquires information
and Firm 2 does not:
θ1 > 0andθ2 = 0, referred to as absolute imitation. One seeks to
identify the conditions under which imitation of this kind is consistent with expected-
profit maximization. Thus, it is assumed that the global maximizer
θ1 lies on the strict
interior of the unit interval: that is,
π 1(E[ax 1; θ]↑~) > max0 — σa0 — C(1)}.2
2 A sufficient but not necessary condition for existence of an interior solution for θ1 is that the conditional variance



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. STIMULATING COOPERATION AMONG FARMERS IN A POST-SOCIALIST ECONOMY: LESSONS FROM A PUBLIC-PRIVATE MARKETING PARTNERSHIP IN POLAND
3. The name is absent
4. Regional specialisation in a transition country - Hungary
5. Comparative study of hatching rates of African catfish (Clarias gariepinus Burchell 1822) eggs on different substrates
6. On the Real Exchange Rate Effects of Higher Electricity Prices in South Africa
7. Regulation of the Electricity Industry in Bolivia: Its Impact on Access to the Poor, Prices and Quality
8. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
9. Beyond Networks? A brief response to ‘Which networks matter in education governance?’
10. The name is absent
11. MANAGEMENT PRACTICES ON VIRGINIA DAIRY FARMS
12. Internationalization of Universities as Internationalization of Bildung
13. The name is absent
14. Public Debt Management in Brazil
15. The name is absent
16. The name is absent
17. Density Estimation and Combination under Model Ambiguity
18. 101 Proposals to reform the Stability and Growth Pact. Why so many? A Survey
19. The name is absent
20. Accurate and robust image superresolution by neural processing of local image representations