Sectoral specialisation in the EU a macroeconomic perspective



spillovers that raise the international correlation
of developments on national financial markets.
On the other hand, financial integration
provides a means for cross-country risk-
sharing that makes it possible to insure a
country’s national income against country-
specific productivity shocks. The increased risk
sharing would raise the business cycle
synchronisation of GNP while the induced
sectoral specialisation may lead to a decreased
cyclical synchronisation of GDP.

Finally, an important feature of business cycles
concerns the co-movement of different sectors
within one country that occurs despite
substantial differences in trend growth paths
and degrees of volatility.16 Sectoral co-
movement may be related to aggregate shocks
when sectors display similar reaction patterns.
If sectoral co-movements are strong enough,
individual sectors will display a common
pattern despite the absence of any correlation
across sector-specific shocks.17 The extent to
which economies are characterised by sectoral
co-movement is of potential importance for
business cycle synchronisation, as it would
mitigate the negative impact of sectoral
specialisation on the harmonisation of business
cycles across EU countries.

Prominent explanations of sectoral co-
movement stress either the sectoral linkages
through a web of input-output relations or
aggregate demand spillovers and trade
externalities that underline the importance of
sectoral shocks for disposable aggregate
income.18 In addition, frictions on capital,
product and labour markets may also contribute
to sectoral co-movement. For instance, when
firms are paying efficiency wages, a sectoral
shock is likely to have an impact upon the
optimal wage-employment mix even in those
sectors that are not directly affected by the
shock. Similarly, when sectoral shocks affect
the value of both tangible and intangible assets,
a re-allocation process may be set off with
repercussions for the aggregate economy.19

16 L. J. Christiano and T. J. Fitzgerald (1998), “The Business Cycle:
It’s Still a Puzzle”, Economic Perspectives, Federal Reserve
Bank of Chicago, Fourth Quarter.

17 R. E. Lucas Jr (1981), “Understanding Business Cycles”, in
Studies in Business-Cycle Theory, R. E. Lucas Jr (ed.),
Cambridge, MA.

18 J. B. Long and C. I. Plosser (1983), “Real Business Cycles”, The
Journal of Political Economy, 91/1; K. M. Murphy, A. Shleifer
and R. W. Vishny (1989) “Increasing Returns, Durables, and
Economic Fluctuations”, NBER Working Paper, 3014.

19 S. J. Davis, J. C. Haltiwanger and S. Schuh (1996), “Job Creation
and Destruction”, Cambridge, MA., pp. 106-108.


ECB

Occasional Paper No. 19

July 2004



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. The fundamental determinants of financial integration in the European Union
3. The Dictator and the Parties A Study on Policy Co-operation in Mineral Economies
4. Proceedings of the Fourth International Workshop on Epigenetic Robotics
5. The Impact of Minimum Wages on Wage Inequality and Employment in the Formal and Informal Sector in Costa Rica
6. ESTIMATION OF EFFICIENT REGRESSION MODELS FOR APPLIED AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS RESEARCH
7. WP RR 17 - Industrial relations in the transport sector in the Netherlands
8. Modelling Transport in an Interregional General Equilibrium Model with Externalities
9. The name is absent
10. Global Excess Liquidity and House Prices - A VAR Analysis for OECD Countries
11. The name is absent
12. Testing Gribat´s Law Across Regions. Evidence from Spain.
13. Dynamic Explanations of Industry Structure and Performance
14. The name is absent
15. Prevalence of exclusive breastfeeding and its determinants in first 6 months of life: A prospective study
16. The name is absent
17. The name is absent
18. Estimating the Economic Value of Specific Characteristics Associated with Angus Bulls Sold at Auction
19. NEW DEVELOPMENTS IN FARM PRICE AND INCOME POLICY PROGRAMS: PART I. SITUATION AND PROBLEM
20. Palkkaneuvottelut ja työmarkkinat Pohjoismaissa ja Euroopassa