where aj ∈ [0, ∞) is j’s effort in the nomination period, unobservable for the principal and
agent k = j . εj is a stochastic noise term, and we assume that ε1 and ε2 are independently
and normally distributed with zero means and precision hε .
We focus on the agents’ efforts aimed at winning the nomination contest here, ab-
stracting from the incentives generated by their work contracts and other career con-
cerns. It would be straightforward to integrate this analysis into a richer model. Agent
j = k ∈ {1, 2} maximizes
Πj aj ; aje, ak, aek = Pj aj ; aje, ak, aek Wj - c(aj),
where Pj aj; aje, ak, aek is the probability of j’s nomination as a function of j’s anticipated
effort ae as well as k’s actual and anticipated effort levels ak and aek. c (•) : R+ → R+ is
an increasing and strictly convex function measuring the disutility of effort. We treat Wj
as exogenous here, but at the end of this section we will discuss ways in which Wj may
be expected to depend on j ’s characteristics, in particular hj .
The principal’s objective is to nominate the most skillful agent; after observing y1 and
y2 he will hence select j if and only if12
E[ηj | yj] > E[ηk | yk].
(1)
Denote by (ɑɪ, a2) the equilibrium effort choices. In equilibrium, each agent’s effort
choice must be optimal given the other agent’s effort choice and beliefs, and the principal
must correctly anticipate effort choices, i.e., ae = a* for j = 1, 2.
Given our normality and independence assumptions, the learning process about each
agent’s skill is well-known. For aje = aj* , the posterior distribution of ηj will be normal
with mean
hjmj + hε (yj - aj*)
(2)
hj + hε
and precision hj + hε .
Let us now consider j ’s effort decision at the beginning of the period. From (2) it
follows that, given ak = a*k , if j chooses aj then he will be nominated with probability
12We implicitly assume here that the principal is risk-neutral, and that the cost of incentive provision
once the agent is nominated, i.e., during the Euro Cup in our soccer example, is unrelated to the agent’s
preceived ability. If h1 = h2, then there exists a biased tournament as in Meyer (1991, 1992) that is
equivalent to the principal’s decision rule. In this biased tournament, the contestant with the lower prior
reputation has to outperform the other agents by a given amount in order to win. For h1 = h2 , the rates
at which the principal updates his beliefs about the agents’ skills as a function of observed outputs differ,
and therefore there is no such direct equivalence.
More intriguing information
1. The name is absent2. The Dictator and the Parties A Study on Policy Co-operation in Mineral Economies
3. Moi individuel et moi cosmique Dans la pensee de Romain Rolland
4. Wirtschaftslage und Reformprozesse in Estland, Lettland, und Litauen: Bericht 2001
5. The mental map of Dutch entrepreneurs. Changes in the subjective rating of locations in the Netherlands, 1983-1993-2003
6. Wirkung einer Feiertagsbereinigung des Länderfinanzausgleichs: eine empirische Analyse des deutschen Finanzausgleichs
7. The name is absent
8. Delayed Manifestation of T ransurethral Syndrome as a Complication of T ransurethral Prostatic Resection
9. Input-Output Analysis, Linear Programming and Modified Multipliers
10. The Variable-Rate Decision for Multiple Inputs with Multiple Management Zones