The name is absent



where aj [0, ∞) is j’s effort in the nomination period, unobservable for the principal and
agent
k = j . εj is a stochastic noise term, and we assume that ε1 and ε2 are independently
and normally distributed with zero means and precision
hε .

We focus on the agents’ efforts aimed at winning the nomination contest here, ab-
stracting from the incentives generated by their work contracts and other career con-
cerns. It would be straightforward to integrate this analysis into a richer model. Agent
j = k {1, 2} maximizes

Πj  aj ; aje, ak, aek  = Pj  aj ; aje, ak, aek  Wj - c(aj),

where Pj aj; aje, ak, aek is the probability of j’s nomination as a function of j’s anticipated
effort
ae as well as k’s actual and anticipated effort levels ak and aek. c () : R+ R+ is
an increasing and strictly convex function measuring the disutility of effort. We treat
Wj
as exogenous here, but at the end of this section we will discuss ways in which Wj may
be expected to depend on
j ’s characteristics, in particular hj .

The principal’s objective is to nominate the most skillful agent; after observing y1 and
y2 he will hence select j if and only if12

E[ηj | yj] > E[ηk | yk].

(1)


Denote by (ɑɪ, a2) the equilibrium effort choices. In equilibrium, each agent’s effort
choice must be optimal given the other agent’s effort choice and beliefs, and the principal
must correctly anticipate effort choices, i.e.,
ae = a* for j = 1, 2.

Given our normality and independence assumptions, the learning process about each
agent’s skill is well-known. For
aje = aj* , the posterior distribution of ηj will be normal
with mean

hjmj + hε (yj - aj*)


(2)


hj + hε

and precision hj + hε .

Let us now consider j ’s effort decision at the beginning of the period. From (2) it
follows that, given
ak = a*k , if j chooses aj then he will be nominated with probability

12We implicitly assume here that the principal is risk-neutral, and that the cost of incentive provision
once the agent is nominated, i.e., during the Euro Cup in our soccer example, is unrelated to the agent’s
preceived ability. If h
1 = h2, then there exists a biased tournament as in Meyer (1991, 1992) that is
equivalent to the principal’s decision rule. In this biased tournament, the contestant with the lower prior
reputation has to outperform the other agents by a given amount in order to win. For h
1 = h2 , the rates
at which the principal updates his beliefs about the agents’ skills as a function of observed outputs differ,
and therefore there is no such direct equivalence.



More intriguing information

1. Forecasting Financial Crises and Contagion in Asia using Dynamic Factor Analysis
2. Volunteering and the Strategic Value of Ignorance
3. LOCAL PROGRAMS AND ACTIVITIES TO HELP FARM PEOPLE ADJUST
4. Innovation and business performance - a provisional multi-regional analysis
5. Perceived Market Risks and Strategic Risk Management of Food Manufactures: Empirical Results from the German Brewing Industry
6. Dynamic Explanations of Industry Structure and Performance
7. The name is absent
8. The name is absent
9. The name is absent
10. The name is absent
11. European Integration: Some stylised facts
12. Migrant Business Networks and FDI
13. 101 Proposals to reform the Stability and Growth Pact. Why so many? A Survey
14. New urban settlements in Belarus: some trends and changes
15. AJAE Appendix: Willingness to Pay Versus Expected Consumption Value in Vickrey Auctions for New Experience Goods
16. The name is absent
17. The name is absent
18. Influence of Mucilage Viscosity On The Globule Structure And Stability Of Certain Starch Emulsions
19. FDI Implications of Recent European Court of Justice Decision on Corporation Tax Matters
20. THE ECONOMICS OF COMPETITION IN HEALTH INSURANCE- THE IRISH CASE STUDY.