Applications of Evolutionary Economic Geography



the same industry, cause the industry to concentrate in one single region even though the
individual firms have different individual preferences. The reason is that once one region has
attracted slightly more entrants than other regions, a critical threshold is passed, and suddenly all
firms will opt for this one region: a case of spatial
lock-in.

In an empirical context, the outcomes of the spin-off model are not easy distinguishable from
the outcomes of the agglomeration economies model. We have, indeed, two different
explanations for the same phenomenon of spatial concentration of an industry. As spin-off
dynamics and agglomeration economies may well contribute to spatial concentration
simultaneously, the challenge for empirical research is to disentangle both processes so as to
assess their presence and importance. One out of the few studies that have attempted to do so is
Klepper’s (2001) study of the U.S. automobile industry. In his econometric analysis, he included
a dummy for being located in the Detroit area. The dummy showed no positive effect on the
survival of firms, which suggests that agglomeration economies were not present. The use of a
Detroit control variable, however, can be questioned, since a subset of firms within the Detroit
area may have benefited from each other’s presence through local networks (Giuliani,
forthcoming) or firms may have benefited from knowledge spillovers over a longer distance
(Jacob and Los, forthcoming). Despite this shortcoming, the result by Klepper (2001) strongly
suggests that the concentration of the U.S. automobile industry in Detroit can be attributed
mainly to the self-reinforcing dynamics of successful firms creating successful spin-offs, creating
successful spin-offs,
et cetera.

A study by Boschma and Wenting (2005) on the spatial evolution of the British automobile
sector came to similar conclusions regarding the self-reinforcing nature of spin-off dynamics,
which, in the British case, led to a concentration in the Birmingham-Coventry area. However,
Boschma and Wenting also accounted for the presence of related industries (such as coach and
cycle making) in a region as a potential source of agglomeration economies, which was shown to
have a positive effect on the survival rate of firms. Thus, the local presence of related industries
appeared to be beneficial due to, for example, knowledge spillovers and skilled labour, yet the
local presence of a high number of firms operating in the same industry turned out to be harmful
due to increased competition, lowering the survival chances of new entrants. Another recent
elaboration on Klepper’s model is by Cantner et al. (2005), whose methodology using
instrumental variable estimation allows for post-entry innovation. In doing so, the survival



More intriguing information

1. Discourse Patterns in First Language Use at Hcme and Second Language Learning at School: an Ethnographic Approach
2. Declining Discount Rates: Evidence from the UK
3. Opciones de política económica en el Perú 2011-2015
4. Happiness in Eastern Europe
5. Three Strikes and You.re Out: Reply to Cooper and Willis
6. The name is absent
7. PROTECTING CONTRACT GROWERS OF BROILER CHICKEN INDUSTRY
8. Modelling Transport in an Interregional General Equilibrium Model with Externalities
9. Cyber-pharmacies and emerging concerns on marketing drugs Online
10. Robust Econometrics
11. Name Strategy: Its Existence and Implications
12. Labour Market Flexibility and Regional Unemployment Rate Dynamics: Spain (1980-1995)
13. Uncertain Productivity Growth and the Choice between FDI and Export
14. Mean Variance Optimization of Non-Linear Systems and Worst-case Analysis
15. Gender and aquaculture: sharing the benefits equitably
16. The Effects of Attendance on Academic Performance: Panel Data Evidence for Introductory Microeconomics
17. Testing the Information Matrix Equality with Robust Estimators
18. The name is absent
19. The name is absent
20. The name is absent