4. Market Clearing under Flexible Prices
Using the definition of the TOT (28) the preceding equations can be rewritten as:
Ct = Ttn-1Yt,
C * _ T nγ *
(34)
(35)
These are the conditions for domestic and foreign goods market clearing, which imply that households
across countries always consume exactly their real incomes (see Obstfeld/Rogoff 2001, p. 8).
Moreover, B0 _ B0* _ 0 together with (14), (29), (30), and (31) also implies that Ct _ Ct* _ Ctw at all
times such that
* w * n-1 n * n * 1-n
Ct _ Ct _ Ct _ nCt + (1 - n)Ct _ nTt Yt + (1 - n)Tt Yt _ Yt (Yt ) ,
while making use of (34) and (35).
In consequence, consumption shares across countries are not only time-constant but even equal (see
Obstfeld/Rogoff 2001, p. 8). Since current and capital accounts between the two countries are in
balance at all times and in all possible states of the world, the mechanism of adjustment to shocks in the
world economy will only be represented by movements in the TOT, but not by changes in the countries’
net asset positions. Hence, international financial markets are redundant anyway such that explicitly
modeling financial market completeness by introducing Arrow-Debreu securities can be waived.
4.2. National Money Markets and World Currency Market
The government is assumed to set its expenditures equal to its revenues at all times such that the
government budget is always in balance and no seignorage can occur (see Obstfeld/Rogoff 1996, p.
523):16
Mt - Mt-1 + Ptτt _ 0.
(36)
Note that an analogous equation to (36) also holds abroad.
Equation (36) describes domestic money supply. Combining (36) with (19) and using the condition
for domestic goods market clearing (34), one obtains two equations in M, which can be set equal and
eventually solved for P :
Pt _
_________Mt-1_________
X 1 ( 1+t ´ 1 ( TnYt* )ε + τt
Making use of (9), an analogous equation in P can be computed abroad such that both equations can
again be set equal and finally solved for S :
St _
■ 1
Mt-1 (X* )1 (+f) ε (TtnYt* )ε + τt*
Mt*-1
■ 1 ■
X1 (⅛t)ε (Tt1 Yt)ρ + τt
As one can see from the above formula, the current equilibrium nominal exchange rate St positively
depends on past domestic nominal money balances Mt-1, current domestic opportunity costs of holding
money it /(1 + it), current foreign output Yt* , and current foreign real lump-sum taxes τt* . The depen-
dence on the remaining variables is of opposite sign, except for the current TOT Tt , whose influence
is ambiguous. An increase of S illustrates a depreciation of the domestic currency, whereas a decrease
characterizes an appreciation.
16One could extend the model by introducing government spending (shocks) (see Obstfeld/Rogoff 2001, pp. 37-38),
which shall be waived for this analysis however.
11
More intriguing information
1. The name is absent2. Human Rights Violations by the Executive: Complicity of the Judiciary in Cameroon?
3. DEMAND FOR MEAT AND FISH PRODUCTS IN KOREA
4. Learning-by-Exporting? Firm-Level Evidence for UK Manufacturing and Services Sectors
5. If our brains were simple, we would be too simple to understand them.
6. Can a Robot Hear Music? Can a Robot Dance? Can a Robot Tell What it Knows or Intends to Do? Can it Feel Pride or Shame in Company?
7. The name is absent
8. The name is absent
9. The name is absent
10. THE WELFARE EFFECTS OF CONSUMING A CANCER PREVENTION DIET