Macroeconomic Interdependence in a Two-Country DSGE Model under Diverging Interest-Rate Rules



5. New Keynesian Framework

with μ := [(1 )(1 — δβ)(p — ξ)] (μ > 0) and μ* := [(1 *)(1 — δ*β)(p — ξ)]* * > 0) representing the
slope coefficients of the NKPCs with respect to the domestic (foreign) output gap. In addition,
ut shall
denote an exogenously given, stationary AR(1) process of the form
ut = ζuut-1 + ηu,t (0 < ζu < 1) with
the exogenous error term
ηu assumed to be i.i.d. ~ N(0, a^u ). This AR(1) process can be interpreted as
a transitory cost-push shock reflecting determinants of real marginal production cost which do not move
proportionally with the output gap (see
Clarida et al. 2001, pp. 250-251).

The two NKPCs represent aggregate supply in both countries and are isomorphic to their closed-economy
counterparts, where (49) can be interpreted as follows: the positive short-run ”trade-off” between current
domestic PPI inflation
πt,H and the current domestic output gap xt can easily be seen.21 However, this
is not really a trade-off to be exploited since
πt,H is also positively related to (discounted) expected
domestic PPI inflation
βEt[πt+1,H].22

Note that an analogous interpretation for (50) also holds abroad. However, u* shall be uncorrelated with
u such that domestic and foreign cost-push shocks are country-specific.

It will turn out to be convenient that the following holds for Et [yfleX] — yflex in case one makes use of
the log-linear version of the current domestic flexible-price equilibrium output according to (38) and its
expected counterpart:

f lex      f l

Et[ У t +1 ] У t

f lex f l

Et [yt+1 ] — yt

( n 1)( P 1)
ξ — ρ


Et [tt+1 ] +


i—1 Et [ a. + 1] + ^.√ ɪ)
ξ — ρ          ξ — ρ .— 1


( n — 1)( p 1)4 ξ — 1

-----1---------tt 7----at

.—p          .—p


. — p'-i . — 1)


7---ln Y

.—p


(n J)(P   1) Et[∆tt ] + .Et[∆at],                            (51)

.—p                   .—p


where at is assumed to obey an exogenously given, stationary random process of the form at = ζaat-1 +
φa a + ηa,t (0 < ζaa < 1) with the exogenous error term ηa assumed to be i.i.d. ~ N (0 ^ a ).

Note that an analogous equation to (51) also holds abroad.

In consequence, the dynamic IS curves (47) and (48) rearrange to:


χt = Et[χt +1] +—{Et[πt+1] it} + -----e E^----EEt[δtt+1] + 7----Etδat +1],             (52)

p                        .—p                   .—p

4 = Et [ x^+1] + 1 {Et [ ∙. —i } + nf-1 Et [∆ tt+1] + I—1 Et [∆ a^].                (53)

t            t+1 p      t+1     t       . p                 . p       t+1


It would also be preferable to express these dynamic IS curves in terms of PPI rather than CPI inflation,
which can be achieved by using the subsequent log-linear representation of the TOT (28):
tt := st +
p* F — pt,H. Subtracting this expression from its expected analog one gets: Et [∆tt+1] = Et [∆st +1 ] +
Et[*+1 F] — Et[πt+1 ,H] = Et[πt +1 ,F] — Et[πt+1 ,H]. Combining this outcome with the log-linear versions
of the domestic CPI (5) and its foreign equivalent, one obtains the following relations between expected
CPI and expected PPI inflation at home and abroad:


Et[πt+1] ≡ Et[πt+1,H] (n — 1)Et[∆tt+1],


Et [ πt+1]  = Et [ π*+1 ,F ] — nEt δ tt+1]


(54)

(55)


21Note that NKPCs such as (49) and (50) in terms of the output gap sometimes are referred to as aggregate supply (AS)
curves (see Clarida et al. 2001, p. 250).

22If, for instance, some institution had the power to raise domestic output above its flexible-price value (given the deviations
from its zero-inflation steady-state value) by raising
πt,H, not only πt,H but also βEt [πt+1,H] would have to rise for
(49) to hold with equality. This means that if output were kept on this artificially high level for an extended period of
time, the respective expected inflation rates would continue to rise at accelerating speed (acceleration theorem).


15




More intriguing information

1. Nurses' retention and hospital characteristics in New South Wales, CHERE Discussion Paper No 52
2. The name is absent
3. Industrial Employment Growth in Spanish Regions - the Role Played by Size, Innovation, and Spatial Aspects
4. ARE VOLATILITY EXPECTATIONS CHARACTERIZED BY REGIME SHIFTS? EVIDENCE FROM IMPLIED VOLATILITY INDICES
5. Developments and Development Directions of Electronic Trade Platforms in US and European Agri-Food Markets: Impact on Sector Organization
6. A dynamic approach to the tendency of industries to cluster
7. The Distribution of Income of Self-employed, Entrepreneurs and Professions as Revealed from Micro Income Tax Statistics in Germany
8. On the Integration of Digital Technologies into Mathematics Classrooms
9. The Institutional Determinants of Bilateral Trade Patterns
10. An Intertemporal Benchmark Model for Turkey’s Current Account
11. The name is absent
12. The name is absent
13. Washington Irving and the Knickerbocker Group
14. Higher education funding reforms in England: the distributional effects and the shifting balance of costs
15. The name is absent
16. Non Linear Contracting and Endogenous Buyer Power between Manufacturers and Retailers: Empirical Evidence on Food Retailing in France
17. Death as a Fateful Moment? The Reflexive Individual and Scottish Funeral Practices
18. Staying on the Dole
19. Evidence of coevolution in multi-objective evolutionary algorithms
20. The name is absent