Mergers under endogenous minimum quality standard: a note



3.1 Low-quality merger: 2 and 3.

The equilibrium values are the following:

qL = 0.2533, ⅛ = 0.0483, qL = 0                    (7)

pL = 0.1076, pL = 0.0102, pL = 0                   (8)

xL = 0.5250, xL = 0.2625, xL = 0                   (9)

πf = 0.0244, 2,3 = 0.00153                      (10)

θL = 0.4748, θL = 0.2125                        (11)

CSl = 0.0433, Wl = 0.0692                    (12)

Where CSl and Wl respectively denote consumer surplus and welfare. This
merger increases the differentiation between high-quality products and is prof-
itable for the insiders and the outsider. This scenario replicates the same results
without regulation in Motta (1993) and Barbot (2007) because the new merged
entity finds it profitable to eliminate the low-quality insider and the consumer
surplus does not depend on its level. Since the high-quality firm is not af-
fected by the low quality and the joint profit of
2 and 3 is maximized when
the lowest quality is zero, then a regulator that maximizes welfare optimally
chooses to eliminate the low quality. All consumers are worse-off, in particular,
i) consumers with preferences lower than θ
2 are not covered after the merger,
ii) consumers in the range
ΘlΘl after the merger receive a lower quality at a
higher price, iii) consumers in the range θ
ɪ θp that after the merger switch
from q
2 to qL, receive a higher quality but at a higher price, and iv) consumers
of the highest quality, with and without the merger, receive a higher quality at
a higher price.3 In such a regulated merger the increase in the aggregate profit
offsets the reduction in consumer surplus. See Figure 1.

3.2 High-quality merger: 1 and 2.

The equilibrium values are:

qf = 0.25, r = 0.11198, qf = 0.09275                (13)

pH = 0.08113, pH = 0.01212, pH = 0.00502             (14)

lj2 = 0.06717, πf = 0.0027                    (15)

CS h = 0.06256 W h = 0.06448                 (16)

0f = 0.5, θH = 0.36945, θH = 0.05414                (17)

θ*

3For instance, for point iii) it is straightforward to see that ʃ-£ (θ (q^) — p^^) —
Z Z      .

⅛L (θ(¾*) P2) = 0.03 5349



More intriguing information

1. Stillbirth in a Tertiary Care Referral Hospital in North Bengal - A Review of Causes, Risk Factors and Prevention Strategies
2. The name is absent
3. AGRICULTURAL TRADE IN THE URUGUAY ROUND: INTO FINAL BATTLE
4. Sex-gender-sexuality: how sex, gender, and sexuality constellations are constituted in secondary schools
5. Housing Market in Malaga: An Application of the Hedonic Methodology
6. Monopolistic Pricing in the Banking Industry: a Dynamic Model
7. IMMIGRATION POLICY AND THE AGRICULTURAL LABOR MARKET: THE EFFECT ON JOB DURATION
8. The name is absent
9. A dynamic approach to the tendency of industries to cluster
10. Quelles politiques de développement durable au Mali et à Madagascar ?