expands in the first phase at relatively high rates above 2.5 percent. Because of the subsistence
effect parents want to have larger families initially and population growth rises. Yet, after
about 30 years survival probabilities are sufficiently good so that the effect of quality-quantity
substitution becomes dominating and population growth begins to decline. This phase is also
characterized by increasing but eventually stabilizing savings rates and education levels. After
about 100 years the demo-economic transition comes to its end and the system stabilizes along
a balanced growth path.
Figure 5: Patterns of Development: Hills, Plateaus, and Valleys
Parameters as for Figure 4 and gA = 0.005, β = 1/3, and α(1 - β) = 0.56.
Now consider an unfavorably located country described by b = 0.0025 and represented by
dashed lines. This country begins also to grow economically after the technology shock but at
a lower rate than the favorably located one. Income growth prospects are increasingly absorbed
by population growth and after about 20 years of promising development economic growth
begins to decline. After reaching a low level of economic growth below one percent - observed
together with perpetually high population growth - almost nothing happens for about 50 years
and some observers (of only this time window) may think that the country has stabilized at a
low-level equilibrium trap. In fact, the economy develops, albeit exceedingly slow. With slightly
but continuously improving child survival rates and thus increasing human capital expenditure,
18