Bidding for Envy-Freeness: A Procedural Approach to n-Player Fair Division Problems



Bidding for envy-freeness

735


Proof. We have

aj :¼ bi(Bj)- bj(Bj)+ dj; i, j a I:

Let p : I ! I be the permutation that transforms the original utilitarian
assignment into the other one; i.e., in the second assignment Player
i receives
the bundle that Player
pði) would receive in the original assignment. Envy-
freeness of the discounts
di in particular yields aii b aipði) .

Taking the sum over differences yields

Еда» - αip(i)) ¼ ∑(d - dp(i)) + ∑(bp(i)(Bp(i))- ЬдВрдо))

¼ 0 + M - M ¼ 0:

Since each addend on the left-hand side is non-negative, and their sum is zero,

aii ¼ aip(i) ; Ei A I:                                                                  r

Said another way, Lemma 5 shows that the compact convex set of all pos-
sible envy-free discount vectors is independent of the utilitarian assignment.10
Note, however, that Lemma 5 says nothing specific about the discount vector
induced by the compensation procedure.

Lemma 6. The compensation procedure yields a unique minimal vector of non-
negative discounts that make a given utilitarian assignment envy-free
.

Proof. Given a utilitarian assignment, the compensation procedure yields a
vector of player discounts
(di) which makes every player envy-free. If there
were some other vector of (non-negative) envy-free player discounts
(mi) which
was smaller for some player, then we obtain a contradiction.

Suppose mk0 dk0 , for player k0. Thus dk0 is strictly positive (because
mk0 b 0), i.e., player k0 was compensated sometime during the compensa-
tion procedure. This implies that in the final envy graph at the conclusion of
the compensation procedure, Player
k0 is not at the root of her tree. Let
k0 ; k1 ; k2 ; ... ; kl ¼ r be the path from k0 to the root r of her tree. Since each
of the arrows in the final envy-graph are double arrows,
akiki ¼ akiki+1 for all
0
a i a l 1. Using (1) to express this in terms of the bids and discounts, we
have

dki ¼ bki (Bk;+i) — bki+ι CBki+ι )+ dki+ι ;

for all 0 a i a l 1. But the (mi ), being an envy-free vector of discounts, must
satisfy

mki b bki (Bki+1 )— bki+1 (Bki+1 )+ mki+1 ;

since the left side is what Player ki would receive under these discounts and the
right side is what Player k
i believes Player ki+1 would receive. Subtracting
these two equations we obtain

10 Lemma 5 corresponds to Aragones’ (1995) Lemma 4.



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. Proceedings of the Fourth International Workshop on Epigenetic Robotics
3. Regionale Wachstumseffekte der GRW-Förderung? Eine räumlich-ökonometrische Analyse auf Basis deutscher Arbeitsmarktregionen
4. The name is absent
5. Should informal sector be subsidised?
6. What Drives the Productive Efficiency of a Firm?: The Importance of Industry, Location, R&D, and Size
7. Heterogeneity of Investors and Asset Pricing in a Risk-Value World
8. The name is absent
9. The name is absent
10. INSTITUTIONS AND PRICE TRANSMISSION IN THE VIETNAMESE HOG MARKET
11. The name is absent
12. Equity Markets and Economic Development: What Do We Know
13. Making International Human Rights Protection More Effective: A Rational-Choice Approach to the Effectiveness of Ius Standi Provisions
14. Structural Conservation Practices in U.S. Corn Production: Evidence on Environmental Stewardship by Program Participants and Non-Participants
15. The name is absent
16. Unemployment in an Interdependent World
17. Gerontocracy in Motion? – European Cross-Country Evidence on the Labor Market Consequences of Population Ageing
18. The name is absent
19. Parent child interaction in Nigerian families: conversation analysis, context and culture
20. Job quality and labour market performance