Bidding for Envy-Freeness: A Procedural Approach to n-Player Fair Division Problems



742


C.-J. Haake et al.

ceding analysis of extreme envy-free prices, we found that 5 is the maximum
discount that Player 1 (the root player) can receive. In contrast, for Player 3,
an increase of 5 is the minimum increment that preserves envy-freeness. The
equal distribution of the remaining surplus thus implements the most favor-
able outcome for the initially non-envious (and therefore uncompensated)
player on the boundary of the set of envy-free prices. This may be di‰cult to
justify in practice.

By contrast, the average discount method acknowledges an additional no-
tion of fairness: Player 1, who did not experience envy throughout the entire
compensation procedure and who is always at the verge of being envied by
Player 2, receives only a small share of the remaining surplus. Player 3, on the
other hand, who quickly becomes envious when other players are compen-
sated, but who is relatively far from being envied by anyone else, receives
a larger share. From a practical viewpoint, the average discounts enhance
the stability of the outcome: by choosing discounts in the interior of the set
of envy-free prices, each player strictly prefers her own bundle to any other
(unless, of course, some players have identical preferences).

6 Cycling to e‰ciency

In problems of fair division that involve only a few parties and a few objects, a
utilitarian assignment will usually be easy to identify in practice. When many
players are involved, the complexity of this initial step quickly rises. Clearly, if
players must rely on computational assistance to perform the necessary cal-
culations before compensations can be made, this will diminish the attractive-
ness of a procedure that is supposed to work without computer support.

In our previous analysis, we used a utilitarian assignment as the starting
point for our procedure, thus ensuring that the envy-free allocation is also ef-
ficient. However, e‰ciency is not just a further desirable property of the out-
come. Indeed, envy-freeness can only be achieved if the assignment of n given
bundles is e‰cient.

Lemma 7. Let d be a vector of envy-free discounts for a given assignment B A B.
Then B must be an e‰cient assignment of the n associated bundles.

Proof. Consider some assignment B A B and an assignment Bp A B, which is
obtained through a permutation
p of the n bundles of B. Let d be the vector
of envy-free discounts associated with the assignment B. Envy-freeness then
implies
aii b aip(i), or, using definition (1),

dib b^Bp^- ЬрдодВрдо)+ dpðŋ :                                      (12)

Since Pidi ¼ Pi∙dp(i) and P bp(i)(Bp(i)) ¼ ∑ibi(Bi), we can sum over both
sides of (12) to obtain

X bi (Bi) b X bi(Bp(i));



More intriguing information

1. Migration and employment status during the turbulent nineties in Sweden
2. The name is absent
3. Concerns for Equity and the Optimal Co-Payments for Publicly Provided Health Care
4. The name is absent
5. Experimental Evidence of Risk Aversion in Consumer Markets: The Case of Beef Tenderness
6. Flatliners: Ideology and Rational Learning in the Diffusion of the Flat Tax
7. ROBUST CLASSIFICATION WITH CONTEXT-SENSITIVE FEATURES
8. The name is absent
9. The name is absent
10. Insecure Property Rights and Growth: The Roles of Appropriation Costs, Wealth Effects, and Heterogeneity
11. Optimal Tax Policy when Firms are Internationally Mobile
12. The name is absent
13. STIMULATING COOPERATION AMONG FARMERS IN A POST-SOCIALIST ECONOMY: LESSONS FROM A PUBLIC-PRIVATE MARKETING PARTNERSHIP IN POLAND
14. Competition In or For the Field: Which is Better
15. The name is absent
16. Weak and strong sustainability indicators, and regional environmental resources
17. Educational Inequalities Among School Leavers in Ireland 1979-1994
18. The name is absent
19. The Making of Cultural Policy: A European Perspective
20. The name is absent