DURABLE CONSUMPTION AS A STATUS GOOD: A STUDY OF NEOCLASSICAL CASES



debt n. Of course, the fact that the long-run stock of debt f is independent of the status
parameter
η does not imply a lack of current account dynamics subsequent to an increase
in η. For example, it is straightforward to show, using the solution for f derived in the
appendix, that the current account, depending on the relative intertemporal dynamics of
durable consumption and output, initially improves (resp. deteriorates) before reaching
a time
t = t*, such that f(t*) = 0. Afterwards, i.e., for t > t*, the current deteriorates
(resp. improves) as the stock of debt returns to its initial and steady-state level, f
o = f,
as t
→ ∞.24

4. Conclusions

In this paper we study the dynamic properties of neoclassical, representative agent models
of the consumer-producer in which status depends on relative consumption. Our extension
is to model in closed and open economy contexts relative consumption as a durable good.
Among our major results, we derive the optimizing equilibria of the closed and open
economies, including their dynamic properties, show that they are all of a fourth order, and
establish that the corresponding steady states in all cases possess the saddlepoint property.
Using a particular speci
hcation of relative consumption preferences, we investigate the
implications of changing the importance of status considerations. Among our results, we
hnd: i) an increase in the degree of status preference in the closed economy with endogenous
work e
ffort raises the long-run levels of durable consumption, its corresponding stock,
employment, and physical capital; and ii) an increase in the status preference parameter
a
ffects the stable speeds of adjustment in the special case of fixed employment, depending
on whether it raises or lowers the intertemporal elasticity of substitution. Finally, the
long-run implications of an increase in status considerations in the small open economy
model are generally similar to those in the closed economy.

24The non-monotonic behavior of the current account reflects the fact that it depends on two stable
eigenvalues. Because
n = no in response to a (permanent) increase in the status parameter η, the solution
of n simpli
fies because in (A15b), Q2 = Q1. From the corresponding expression for n, we can show

rι (t*) = 0


,    ,*     ln(θ2θ1)

t = t = θι θ2

22



More intriguing information

1. LIMITS OF PUBLIC POLICY EDUCATION
2. Strategic Planning on the Local Level As a Factor of Rural Development in the Republic of Serbia
3. Confusion and Reinforcement Learning in Experimental Public Goods Games
4. ENERGY-RELATED INPUT DEMAND BY CROP PRODUCERS
5. Regional science policy and the growth of knowledge megacentres in bioscience clusters
6. The name is absent
7. The name is absent
8. Restricted Export Flexibility and Risk Management with Options and Futures
9. DISCRIMINATORY APPROACH TO AUDITORY STIMULI IN GUINEA FOWL (NUMIDA MELEAGRIS) AFTER HYPERSTRIATAL∕HIPPOCAMP- AL BRAIN DAMAGE
10. ESTIMATION OF EFFICIENT REGRESSION MODELS FOR APPLIED AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS RESEARCH
11. Opciones de política económica en el Perú 2011-2015
12. Getting the practical teaching element right: A guide for literacy, numeracy and ESOL teacher educators
13. Fertility in Developing Countries
14. The name is absent
15. Linking Indigenous Social Capital to a Global Economy
16. Governance Control Mechanisms in Portuguese Agricultural Credit Cooperatives
17. An Estimated DSGE Model of the Indian Economy.
18. The Prohibition of the Proposed Springer-ProSiebenSat.1-Merger: How much Economics in German Merger Control?
19. Dual Track Reforms: With and Without Losers
20. Regional specialisation in a transition country - Hungary