Proposition 1 Suppose that λj and δj are common across j . Suppose that sj,t is
a random variable which follows a uniform distribution independently across j. Then
m0∕>∕N asymptotically follows a normal distribution with mean zero and variance μ(1-
μ). Let m be a positive integer. ∣W∣ conditional to ∣m0∣ = m follows a distribution
function asymptotically as we take ξ → 1 first and then N → ∞:
Pr(∣W ∣ = w ∣ ∣m0∣ = m) = (m∕w)e-φw (φw)w-m∕(w - m)! (19)
for w = m, m + 1, .... The tail of the probability function is approximated by:
Pr(∣W∣ = w ∣ ∣m0∣ = m) ≈ (m(φe)-m∕√2π)(φe1-φ)ww-1.5 (20)
The unconditional distribution of W is symmetric.
Proof is deferred to Appendix A.1. The key to the proof is to embed the best
response dynamics in a branching process so that the recursivity of the branching
process becomes available. Let G(s) be the generating function of the total adjustment
W given the initial deviation from the time average level, m0 = 1. Let x be the number
of sectors that adjust capital due to m0, and F (s) be its generating function. Each
adjustment of x then has a chance to propagate in the next step just like the initial
adjustment m0 . Thus the total number of offsprings which are originated from each
of x follows G(s). Hence we obtain a functional equation G(s) = sF (G(s)), from
which we derive the distribution of W . A similar functional equation obtains for a
large class of models with features such as heterogeneous λi and δi , non-uniformly
distributed sj0,t, or non-constant returns to scale technology, as shown in Nirei (2003).
The functional equation characterizes the propagation distribution completely, because
all the moments can be derived from it.
Proposition 1 implies that the capital growth log kt+1 - log kt conditional to m0 is
approximated by a power distribution w-1.5 truncated by an exponential distribution
that declines at rate 1 - φ. We can calculate moments when φ < 1. The capital
growth conditional to m0 = 1 has an asymptotic mean log λ∕(N (1 - φ)) and variance
(log λ∕N)2(2 - φ)∕(1 - φ)3. The variance of an unconditional capital growth rate is
calculated as ((logλ)2∕N)(μ(1 — μ)(1 — 2∕π)/(1 — φ)2 + ^2μ(1 — μ)/(πN)/(1 — φ)3) by
approximating m0 by an integer random variable. This is a natural result as obtained
in usual models: a fraction μ of sectors are induced to adjust by the deterministic trend
in mean. The variance of the capital growth rate declines linearly in N , hence the law
of large numbers obtains. One notable difference is that the variance has a 1∕(1 — φ)3
term, which can be quite large when φ is close to one. In a continuously adjusting
10
More intriguing information
1. Brauchen wir ein Konjunkturprogramm?: Kommentar2. The name is absent
3. The name is absent
4. The name is absent
5. The name is absent
6. Transport system as an element of sustainable economic growth in the tourist region
7. Der Einfluß der Direktdemokratie auf die Sozialpolitik
8. Does South Africa Have the Potential and Capacity to Grow at 7 Per Cent?: A Labour Market Perspective
9. Optimal Private and Public Harvesting under Spatial and Temporal Interdependence
10. Macroeconomic Interdependence in a Two-Country DSGE Model under Diverging Interest-Rate Rules